Burlington v Dague Sr Brief for Respondents

Public Court Documents
January 1, 1992

Burlington v Dague Sr Brief for Respondents preview

65 pages

Cite this item

  • Brief Collection, LDF Court Filings. Burlington v Dague Sr Brief for Respondents, 1992. eaac1e19-b79a-ee11-be36-6045bdeb8873. LDF Archives, Thurgood Marshall Institute. https://ldfrecollection.org/archives/archives-search/archives-item/e5badf9d-0ede-42fa-8863-40d25451955f/burlington-v-dague-sr-brief-for-respondents. Accessed October 11, 2025.

    Copied!

    No. 91-810

In The

Supreme Court of the United States
October Term, 1991 

----------_— *---------------

CITY OF BURLINGTON, 

vs.
Petitioner,

ERNEST DAGUE, SR., ERNEST DAGUE, JR., 
BETTY DAGUE, AND ROSE A. BESSETTE,

Respondents.

On Writ Of Certiorari To The United States Court 
Of Appeals For The Second Circuit

—  ---------------------— ♦ ----------------------------------------

BRIEF FOR RESPONDENTS

G uy T. Saperstein 
M ari M ayeda 
Barry G oldstein 
Saperstein, M ayeda, 
Larkin & G oldstein 
1300 Clay Street 
11th Floor 
Oakland, CA 94612 
(510) 763-9800
Co-Counsel for

Respondents

W illiam W. P earson*
M olloy, Jones & D onahue, P.C. 
33 North Stone Avenue 
Suite 2100
Tucson, Arizona 85701 
(602) 620-5520
Counsel for Respondents

*Counsel of Record

COCKLE LAW BRIEF PRINTING CO., (800) 225-6964 
OR CALL COLLECT (402) 342-2831



1

STATEMENT OF THE C A S E ...............................................  1

Summary Of The Litigation On The M erits.................  1

A ttorneys’ Fee Award............................................    2

SUMMARY OF A R G U M E N T ...............................................  5

ARGUM ENT.................................................................................  6

I. A REASO NA BLE FEE FOR A CASE PR O S­
ECUTED ON A CONTINGENT FEE BASIS MAY 
INCLUDE AN ADJUSTMENT FOR THE CON­
TINGENT RISK OF L O SS........................................... 6

A. This Court Consistently Has Accepted Legal
M arketplace Principles In Determining What 
Are Reasonable Fees Under Fee-Shifting Stat­
utes ...............................................................................  6

B. Justice O ’C onnor’s Analysis of the Contingent
Adjustment in Delaware Valley II  Is Consistent 
With This Court’s Adherence To M arket Prin­
ciples ..........................................................................  12

II. LEGISLATION PROVIDING FOR THE AWARD 
OF REASONABLE ATTORNEY’S FEES TO A 
PREVAILING PARTY INCORPORATES LEGAL 
MARKETPLACE FACTORS........................................  13

A. The Language of the Statutes Demonstrate 
That Congress Did Not Intend to Depart From
Its Historic Reliance on the M arket Model . . 13

B. The Legislative History Adopts Marketplace Stan­
dards For Calculating a “Reasonable Fee” ........... 21

TABLE OF CONTENTS
Page



C. Recognition of the Risk Premium Is Consistent
With The Design, Object and Policy of the 
S ta tu tes ........................................................................  26

D, Risk Adjustments Do Not Compensate Non-
Prevailing Parties.....................................................  30

III. THE TEST SET FORTH BY JUSTICE O ’CONNOR
IN DELAWARE VALLEY II IS CONSISTENT WITH
M ARKET PR IN C IPLES AND HAS PROVEN
W ORKABLE..................................     34

A. N early  A ll C ourts Have A pplied  Justice
O ’C onnor’s Concurrence C orrec tly ...................  34

B. As With Other Economic Markets, the Legal
M arketplace Normally Provides a Risk Pre­
mium For Cases Taken on a Contingency-Fee 
B a s is ............................................................................. 39

1. Contingency Fee Cases Norm ally Com­
mand Higher Fees than Fees for Work on 
Noncontingency M a tte rs ................................  39

2. Contingency Enhancements in the Legal
M arketplace Find W ell-Established Paral­
lels in M odem Economic Theory Regard­
ing How Markets O p e ra te ............................ 40

3. C ourt-A w arded C ontingency  E nhance­
ments are Nothing More Than the M ini­
mum Risk Premium Required by the Legal 
M arketplace to Attract Counsel to Fee- 
Shifting C ases ...................................................  41

C. The City and Amici Seek a Radical Departure
from Basic M arketplace P rin c ip le s ...................  43

TABLE OF CONTENTS -  Continued
Page



Ill

TABLE OF CONTENTS -  Continued
Page

D, The Objections Made by The City and Amici
Regarding the Need for and Operation of the 
Contingency Risk Factor Are Addressed by 
Justice O ’C onnor’s Two-Prong T e s t ............ .. 44

E. D eterm ination  o f the A ppropriate  M arket- 
Based Contingency Adjustment is a Judicial,
Not Legislative, T a s k .............................................  48

IV. THE DISTRICT COURT PROPERLY EXERCISED 
ITS D ISC RETIO N  W HEN IT AWARDED AN 
E N H A N C E M E N T  OF TH E LO D ESTA R  FEE 
BASED UPON CONTINGENT RISK ........................  49

CO N CLU SIO N .....................     50



IV

C ases

A ngoff v. Goldfine, 270 F.2d 185 (1st Cir. 1959).............  16

Blanchard  v. Bergeron, 489 U.S. 87 (1 9 8 9 )...............passim

Blank v. Talley Indus., Inc., 390 F.Supp. 1 (S.D N Y
1975)..............................................................................................  15

Blum v. Stenson, 465 U.S. 886 (1984).......................... passim

Blum  v. Witco Chem. Corp., 829 F.2d 367 (3d Cir.
1987) (Blum I ) ........... ...............................................................35

Blum  v. Witco Chem. Corp., 888 F.2d 975 (3d Cir.
1989) (Blum II) . . .. ..............................................   35

Bradley v. United States, 410 U.S. 605 (1 9 7 3 ).................  16

Cherner v. Transitron Electronic Corp., 221 F.Supp.
55 (D.M ass. 1963) m odified on other grounds,
Green v. Transitron Electronic Corp., 326 F.2d 492 
(1st Cir. 1 9 6 4 ) ..........................................................................  15

Christiansburg Garment Co. v. EEOC, 434 U.S. 412
(1 9 7 8 )............... .............................................. .............. .. 32, 47

City o f  Detroit v. Grinnell Corp., 495 F.2d 448 (2nd
Cir. 1 9 7 4 ) ...................................................................................  15

City o f  Riverside v. Rivera, A l l  U.S. 561 (1986)...............8

Colson v. Hilton Hotels Corp., 59 F.R.D. 324 (N D
HI. 1 9 7 3 )....................................    15

Conklin v. Lovely, 834 F.2d 543 (6th Cir. 1987)...............  36

Crawford Fitting Co. v. J.T. Gibbons, 482 U.S. 437
(1987 )...................................... ............................... 5, 14, 19, 20

TABLE OF AUTH ORITIES
Page



V

Curry v. Contract Fabricators Profit Sharing Plan,
744 F.Supp. 1061 (M.D. Ala. 1988), a ff’d, 891 F.2d 
842 (11th Cir. 1990)................................................................  38

Davis v. County o f  Los Angeles, 8 Empl. Prac. Dec.
(CCH) f  9444 (C.D. Cal. June 5, 1974).................  24, 25

D ’Emanuele v. M ontgomery Ward & Co., 904 F.2d
1379 (9th Cir. 1990)................................................................  37

Department o f  Labor v. Triplett, 494 U.S. 715 (1990)
......................... .. .......................... ......................................5, 11, 47

Duke v. Uniroyal, Inc., 743 F.Supp. 1218 (E.D.N.C.
1990), a ff’d in part and rev’d in part on other 
grounds, 928 F.2d 1413 (4th Cir. 1 9 9 1 ) ............................ 35

Evans v. J e ff  D., 475 U.S. 717 (1986)..................................  28

F.C.C. v. American Broadcasting Co., Inc., 347 U.S.
284 (1954)...................................................................................  17

Fadhl v. City o f  San Francisco, 859 F.2d 649 (9th Cir.
1988) ........................................................................................... 37

Franchise Tax Bd. v. United States Postal Service,
467 U.S. 512 (1984)................................................................  30

Hasbrouck v. Texaco, Inc., 879 F.2d 632 (9th Cir.
1989) ...........................................................................................  37

Hendrickson  v. Branstad, 934 F.2d 158 (8th Cir. 1991) . . . .  37

Hensley v. Eckerhart, 461 U.S. 424 (1 9 8 3 ) ................. passim

Hidle v. Geneva County Bd. o f  Educ., 681 F.Supp. 752
(M.D. Ala. 1988).............................................................. 39, 46

In re Coordinated Pretrial Proceedings, Etc., 410
F.Supp. 680 (D. Minn. 1 9 7 5 ) . . . ......................................... 15

C ases -  C ontinued

Page



VI

In re Detroit I n f  l Bridge Co., I l l  F.2d 235 (6th Cir.
1940)..............................................................................................  16

In re Gypsum Cases, 386 F.Supp. 959 (N.D. Cal.
1974), a ff’d, 565 F.2d 1123 (9th Cir. 1977) . . . . . . . . .  15

In re Osofsky, 50 F.2d 925 (1 9 3 1 ) ...........................................  16

In re Wicat Securities Litigation, 671 F.Supp. 726 (D.
Utah 1987).............................................................    39

Independent Fed’ n o f  Flight Attendants v. Zipes, 491
U.S. 754 (1989).....................................................    33

Islamic Center o f  M ississippi, Inc. v. Starkville, 876
F.2d 465 (5th Cir. 1 9 8 9 )..........................................................  36

Johnson  v. Georgia Highway Express, Inc., 488 F.2d
714 (5th Cir. 1974)..................................................... 7, 23, 24

Jones v. Diamond, 636 F.2d 1364, 1382 (5th Cir.),
cert, dism issed , 453 U.S. 950 (1981)............................... 23

King v. Bd. o f Regents, 748 F.Supp, 686 (E.D. Wis.
1990).............................................................    36

King v. Palmer, 950 F.2d 771 (D.C. Cir. 1991)......... 34, 35

Lapina v. Williams, 232 U.S. 78 (1 9 1 4 ) ..............................20

Leigh v. Engle, 714 F.Supp. 1465 (N.D. 111. 1989)........... 37

Lindy Bros. Builders, Inc. v. American Radiator & 
Standard Sanitary Corp., 487 F.2d 161 (3d Cir.
1973).....................................................................................  15, 23

Lindy Bros. Builders, Inc. v. American Radiator & 
Standard Sanitary Corp., 540 F.2d 102 (3d Cir.
1976).............................................................................................. 39

C ases — C ontinued

Page



M cKenzie v. Kennickell, 875 F.2d 330 (D.C. Cir.
1989)..............................................................................................  35

M cKittrick v. Gardner, 378 F.2d 872 (4th Cir. 1967) . . . .  16

McNary v. Haitian Refugee Center, Inc., I l l  S.Ct.
888 (1991)...................................................................................  16

M arks v. United States, 161 U.S. 297 (1896)............   14

M artin  v. Univ. o f  South Alabama, 911 F.2d 604 (11th
Cir. 1 9 9 0 ) ...................................................................................  38

M issouri v. Jenkins, 491 U.S. 274 (1 9 8 9 ) ...5 , 8, 9, 10, 30

M orris v. American N at’l Can Corp., 952 F.2d 200
(8th Cir. 1 991 )..................................................................  37, 46

Newman v. Piggie Park Enterprises, Inc., 390 U.S.
400 (1968)...................................................................................  31

Norman v. Housing Auth., 836 F.2d 1292 (11th Cir.
1988).............................................................................................. 38

Pennsylvania  v. Delaware Valley Citizen’s Counsel fo r
Clean Air, 478 U.S. 556 (1986).....................................passim

Pennsylvania  v. Delaware Valley C itizen’s Counsel fo r
Clean Air, 483 U.S. 711 (1987).................................... passim

Perlman v. Feldmann, 160 F.Supp. 310 (D. Conn.
1958).............................................................    16

Pilot Life Ins. Co. v. Dedeaux, 481 U.S. 41 (1987)......... 26

Ramos v. Lamm. 713 F.2d 546 (10th Cir. 1983)................ 9

Skelton v. General M otors Corp., 860 F.2d 250 (7th
Cir. 1988), cert, denied, 493 U.S. 810 (1989)...............  36

Smith v. Freeman, 921 F.2d 1120 (10th Cir. 1990)........... 37

Vl l

C ases — C ontinued

Page



V l l l

Soto  v. Adams Elevator Equip. Co., 941 F.2d 543 (7th
Cir. 1 9 9 1 ) ..................................................................................... 36

Spell v. M cDaniel, 824 F.2d 1380 (4th Cir. 1 9 8 7 )..........  35

Stainback v. Mo Hock Ke Lok Po, 336 U.S. 368
( 1 9 4 9 ) . . . ................................................................................   16

Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 221 U.S. 1 (1911) . . . .  16

Stanford Daily v. Zurcher, 64 F.R.D. 680 (N.D. Cal.
1974), a ff’d, 550 F.2d 464 (9th Cir. 1977), rev’d,
436 U.S. 547 (1 9 7 8 ) . . ...........................  23, 24, 25, 28, 45

C ases — C ontinued

Page

Steinberg v. Hardy, 93 F.Supp. 873 (D. Conn. 1950) . . . .  15

Student Pub. Interest Research Group v. AT&T Bell
Laboratories, 842 F.2d 1436 (3d Cir. 1988)...................  35

Swann v. Charlotte-M ecklenburg Bd. o f Educ., 66
F.R.D. 483 (W.D.N.C. 1975)........................................  24, 25

Texas State Teachers A ss’ n. v. Garland Indep. School
Dist., 489 U.S. 782 (1 9 8 9 )...................................................  31

United States v. Great N. R. R. Co., 287 U.S. 144
(1932 )...........................................................................................  20

United States v. M onia, 317 U.S. 424 (1 9 4 3 ) ...................  16

United States v. Wilson, 60 U.S.L.W. 4244 (1992)........... 17

Vargas v. Calabrese, 750 F.Supp. 677 (D.N.J. 1990) . . . .  35

Venegas v. M itchell, 495 U.S. 82 (1990)...............10, 11, 33

Walters v. National Assn, o f  Radiation Survivors, 473
U.S. 305 (1985 ).........................................................  18, 28, 47

West Virginia Univ. Hosp. v. Casey, 111 S.Ct. 1138
(1 9 9 1 )............................................................ 14, 17, 19, 20, 32



IX

W olf v. Planned Property M anagement, 735 F.Supp.
882 (N.D. III. 1 9 9 0 )................................................................  37

W ulfv. City o f  Wichita, 883 F.2d 842 (10th Cir. 1989) . . . .  38 

Statutes

American-M exican Chamizal Convention Act o f 1964,
22 U.S.C. §277(1-21. ........................................................ 19

Antitrust Civil Process Act Amendments o f 1976, 15
U.S.C. § 1 5 g (l)(A )-(B )..............................................................18

Black Lung Benefit Act, 30 U.S.C. §§901 et s e q . . . .  11, 47

Civil Rights Act o f  1 9 9 1 ............................................................. 20

Civil Rights A ttorneys’ Fees Awards Act, 42 U.S.C.
§1988 .......................  -14

Clayton Act o f 1914, 15 U.S.C. §15..................... ................ 15

Clean Air Act o f  1970, 42 U.S.C. §§7401 et seq ..............28

Comprehensive Environmental Response, Compensation and 
Liability Act (CERCLA),

42 U.S.C. §§9601 et seq ...........................................................19

42 U.S.C. §9659(f) .................................................  19

Equal Access to Justice Act, 28 U.S.C.
§2414(d)(1 )(A )...............................................................  18

Federal Tort Claims Act, 28 U.S.C. §2678.......................... 18

Federal Water Pollution Control Act (Clean Water Act),

33 U.S.C. §§1251.......................   passim

33 U.S.C. §1362(5 )..................................................................  30

33 U.S.C. §136 5 (d ) ..................................................... 2, 13, 28

C ases -  C ontinued
Page







The Effect o f  Legal Fees on the Adequacy o f Repre­
sentation: Hearings Before the Subcomm. On Rep.
O f Citizen Interests o f the Senate Judiciary Com­
mittee, 93d Cong., 1st Sess. (1 9 7 3 ) ..................................  71

R. Evans & R. W einstein, Ranking Occupations as 
Risky Income Prospects, 35 Indus. & Lab, Rel. Rev.
252 (1982)................................................................................. , 41

House Committee on Interstate and Foreign Com­
merce, 94th Cong., 2d Sess.................................................. 23

H.R. 5757, 98th Cong., 2d Sess. (1 9 8 4 )...... .......................20

H.R. 3181, 99th Cong., 1st Sess. (1985)..............................  23

H.R. Rep. No. 1558, 94th Cong., 2d Sess. (1 9 7 6 )........... 21

Joint Conference Report for Individuals with D isabil­
ities in Education Act, reprinted in, 1986 U.S. Code 
Conf. & Ad. N e w s .................................................................. 26

A. G. King, Occupational Choice, Risk Aversion, and
Wealth, 27 Indus. & Lab. Rel. Rev. 586 (1 9 7 2 )........... 41

The Legal Fee Equity Act [S.2802]: Hearing Before 
the Subcomm. on the Constitution o f the Senate 
Judiciary Committee, 98th Cong., 2d Sess., 38-41 
(1984 )....................................................................  . . . 2 0

Legal Fees Equity Act [S.1580]: Hearing Before the 
Subcomm. on the Constitution o f the Senate Judici­
ary Committee, 99th Cong., 1st Sess. 47-51 (1985) 20, 29

Legislative History o f  the Toxic Substances Control
Act, 255-56 (Comm. Print 1976).......................................  23

F.B. M acKinnon, Contingent Fees For Legal Ser­
vices: A Report o f the American Bar Foundation,
26 (1964)...................     16

xii

M iscellaneous  — C ontinued

Page



H. Newberg, Attorney Fee Awards, 142 (1986).................  45

R. Posner, Economic Analysis o f  Law, 534 (3d ed.
1986) 54 Geo. Wash. L. Rev. (1986).......................  39, 41

R. Posner, Law and the Theory o f  Finance: Some
Intersections, 54 Geo. Wash. L. Rev. 159 (1986)......... 41

S. Rep. No. 414, 92d Cong., 2d Sess. (1972) reprinted
in 1972 U.S. Code Cong. & Ad. News 3668.................  28

S. Rep. No. 1011, 94th Cong., 2d Sess. 6 (1 9 7 6 ) ............. 22

S. 585, 97th Cong., 2d Sess. §722(A)(e) (1982).................. 19

S. 1580, 99th Cong., 1st Sess. (1 9 8 5 ).................................  20

S. 2802, 98th Cong., 2d Sess. (1984)...................................  20

W. Sharpe, Capital Asset Prices With and Without 
Negative Holdings, 46 Journal of Finance 489 
(1 9 9 1 )....................................................... ................................... 40

Adam Smith, The Nature and Causes o f  the Wealth o f
Nations, 106 (Modern Library ed. 1937).......................... 40

2A Sutherland Statutory Construction, §45.12, §51.02
(5th ed. 1992)....................................................................  14, 17

137 Cong. Rec. S. 15338-39 (daily ed. Oct. 29, 1991) . . . .  20

X l l l

M iscellaneo us  -  C ontinued
Page



STATEM ENT OF TH E CASE

It is undisputed in the record in this case that the market 
for legal services ordinarily compensates attorneys for the 
risk taken in contingent cases. This Court m ust decide 
whether, regardless of the operation of this market for legal 
services, the district court lacked authority to consider market 
treatm ent of risk in setting a reasonable attorney’s fee.

Sum m ary O f The Litigation On The M erits

Seven years ago, in April 1985, Respondents (“Dagues”) 
hired their attorneys to represent them in a lawsuit concerning 
hazardous wastes dumped into Petitioner’s (“City”) municipal 
landfill (“Landfill”). Jt. App. I at 24. The Dagues’ attorneys 
took this case on a contingency fee basis. They assumed the 
risk of receiving no attorneys’ fees at all unless the Dagues 
prevailed in their lawsuit. Jt. App. at 24 and App. I at 132.

The Dagues own homes next to the Landfill. App. I at 89. 
Beginning in 1950, thousands of gallons of hazardous waste 
were dumped in the Landfill. App. I at 94-95. By 1985, 
methane gas in explosive concentrations was crossing the 
Landfill boundary onto the D agues’ property. App. I at 99, 
102.

On the opposite side of the Landfill from the Dagues’ 
property is a wetland called the Intervale. App. I at 89-90. As 
a result of tests conducted in 1980, the City learned that 
Landfill leachate contam inated with hazardous and toxic 
chemicals was being discharged into the Intervale directly 
below the Landfill. App. I at 92, 98.

On October 9, 1985, the Dagues filed suit to compel the 
City to comply with the Clean Water Act, 33 U.S.C. §§1251 et 
seq. (“CWA”), the Resource Conservation and Recovery Act, 
42 U.S.C. §§6901 et seq. (“RCRA”), and state environmental 
laws. App. II at 244-69. After a vigorously contested and 
highly technical trial (App. I at 65-67, 77-81, 133), on Octo­
ber 16, 1989, the district court found that the City had 
violated the CWA and RCRA (App. I at 87-88), and ordered

1



2

the City to close its Landfill and pay the costs of litigation, 
including reasonable attorney and expert fees under 42 U.S.C. 
§6972(e) and 33 U.S.C. § 1365(d). App. I at 88-89. The 
Second Circuit affirmed the district court “in all respects.” 
App. I at 37.

A tto rneys’ Fee A w ard

In support of their Application for Award of Fees and 
Costs (Jt. App. I at 5-218), the Dagues filed a memorandum 
(Jt. App. I at 7-17), two affidavits by trial counsel (Jt. App. I 
at 17-32), a detailed bill itemizing work, hours, services and 
rates and expert fees and costs (Jt. App. I at 32-210), and 
three affidavits by experienced attorneys fam iliar with the 
legal marketplace. Jt. App. I at 211-218.

Attorneys William Pearson and Richard Bland provided 
the vast m ajority o f legal services. Pearson’s hourly rates 
ranged from $85.00 per hour to $125.00 per hour and B land’s 
ranged from $45.00 per hour to $80.00 per hour. The overall 
composite hourly rate charged in the Dagues’ first fee petition 
was $64.35 per hour.

The affidavits o f experienced counsel established that: 
(1) the hourly rates the D agues’ attorneys charged were the 
prevailing rates for hourly work in the Burlington m ar­
ketplace (Jt. App. I at 212, 215, 217); (2) when contingency 
fee arrangements are made in the Burlington marketplace, a 
percentage of fee recovery is fixed at a level which would be 
larger than for work done on an hourly basis to reflect the risk 
of no recovery (Jt. App. I at 212, 215); (3) lawyers in the 
Burlington marketplace who take contingency work expect to 
receive a m ultiple of their usual hourly rate if they prevail (Jt. 
App. I at 217-18); and (4) without this expectation of an 
enhancement, there is no incentive to take this work (Id.).

The City opposed the D agues’ fee application claiming 
they did not substantially prevail. Jt. App. I at 219-29, 
236-81. However, the City neither challenged the reasonable­
ness of the hourly rates (Pet. Brief 6), nor did it counter any



3

of the D agues’ evidence regarding the operation of the mar­
ketplace for legal services. After a hearing, the district court 
aw arded the D agues a fu ll a tto rn e y s ’ fee lodesta r of 
$198,027.50, plus expenses of $10,929.66, together with a 
25% attorneys’ fee enhancement. App. I at 130-34. The Court 
justified the enhancement on the basis o f its findings that 
“p lain tiff’s attorneys would not have been compensated at all 
unless plaintiffs prevailed” (App. I at 132), that “the risk of 
not prevailing was substantial under the facts here,” and that 
“absent an opportunity for enhancement, plaintiff would have 
faced substantial difficulty in obtaining counsel of reasonable 
skill and competence in this complicated field of law.” App. I 
at 132-33.

The Dagues requested a separate delay enhancement 
given the long history of the case without any fee payment. 
App. I at 13. The district court refused, deciding that the 25% 
enhancem ent was adequate in order to compensate for delay 
in payment as well as risk. App. I at 133. Therefore, the 
district court awarded a lodestar that was based only on 
historic rates without a separate adjustment for the delay in 
payment.

In affirming the lower court “in all respects,” the Second 
Circuit expressly rejected the C ity’s claim that the Dagues 
had not substantially prevailed “because, in large part, it was 
the pressure generated by the plain tiffs’ efforts that caused 
the city to actually close the landfill [and ojnly by bringing 
this suit against the city were the plaintiffs finally able to get 
from the city action as opposed to mere promises.” App. I at 
30-31.

The Second Circuit also affirmed the lower court’s lode­
star award and the 25% risk enhancement. App. I at 35-37. In 
particular, the Court affirmed the finding that “without the 
possibility of fee enhancement . . . competent counsel might 
refuse to represent clients thereby denying them effective



4

access to the court.” App. I at 37 .1 On June 26, 1991, the City 
filed a Petition for Rehearing and Suggestion for Rehearing 
en banc, which was denied on August 20, 1991. App. I at 
145-46.

The City filed its Petition for a Writ of Certiorari on 
November 18, 1991. On January 27, 1992, this Court granted 
the Petition on the single question of whether courts have 
authority to consider the risk o f nonpayment o f any fees in a 
contingent case when determining a reasonable attorney's fee 
under the fee shifting provisions in the CWA and RCRA.

The D agues’ attorneys have provided legal services for 
seven years in a difficult case in a complicated field of law, 
carried the risk of not receiving any payment for their ser­
vices, achieved a substantial result for their clients, charged 
an overall composite rate of $67.58 for their services, and

1 On June 25, 1991, following their success in the Second Circuit, 
the Dagues filed a Supplemental Application for Award of Fees and Costs 
in the District Court, and an Initial Application For Award of Fees and 
Costs Incurred on Appeal in the Second Circuit. The District Court 
Supplemental Application requested a $24,113.00 lodestar, a 25% fee 
enhancement and $2,707.61 in expenses. Jt. App. II at 311-55. The 
Second Circuit Application requested a $53,315.00 lodestar, a 25% 
enhancement and $2,240.00 in expenses. Jt. App. II at 356-417. Both 
applications were in substantially the same format as the original district 
court application, including affidavits from experienced attorneys in the 
legal marketplace. The City did not file any opposing memoranda or 
affidavits to either of the supplemental applications.

On October 11, 1991, the district court issued an Order granting 
supplemental attorneys’ fees in the amount of $24,113.00, and expenses 
of $2,707.61, together with a 25% enhancement of the attorneys’ fees. 
App. II at 137-38.

On October 25, 1991, the Second Circuit issued an Order granting 
the Dagues supplemental attorneys’ fees in the amount of $24,113.00, and 
expenses of $2,707.61 but denied a 25% “risk enhancement” on the 
ground that the “risk” involved in defending an appeal is not significant. 
App. I at 38-39.



5

have not, as of yet, received any payment for their time or even 
reimbursement for their advancement of expert fees and costs.

SUMMARY OF ARGUMENT

In determining what are reasonable attorneys’ fees under 
prevailing party statutes, this Court consistently has relied on the 
principles and practices of the legal marketplace. Hensley v. 
Eckerhart, 461 U.S. 414 (1983); Blum v. Stenson, 465 U.S. 886 
(1984); Missouri v. Jenkins, 491 U.S. 274 (1989). This Court has 
repeatedly emphasized the congressional purpose behind fee-shift­
ing statutes as providing incentives for competent private attorneys 
to enforce civil rights, environmental, and antitrust statutes. Id. In 
Pennsylvania v. Delaware Valley Citizen’s Council for Clean Air, 
483 U.S. 711 (1987) (Delaware Valley II), a majority of the Court 
held that legal marketplace conditions may require enhancement of 
the lodestar fee to account for the risk of loss in order to attract 
competent counsel to prosecute such cases. In Department of 
Labor v. Triplett, 494 U.S. 715 (1990), this Court recognized that 
an adjustment of an attorney’s fee for the contingent risk of loss 
was permitted as part of a “reasonable attorney’s fee.” See Section 
I, infra.

The phrase “reasonable attorney’s fee” meant to Congress 
what it meant in the antitrust and securities statutes that had been 
earlier enacted by Congress: that the risks of contingent representa­
tion may require additional compensation. If Congress intended to 
limit the courts’ consideration of marketplace factors, it would 
have done so because “[i]t is . . . clear that when Congress meant 
to set a limit on fees, it knew how to do so.” Crawford Fitting Co. 
v. J.T. Gibbons, 482 U.S. 437, 442 (1987). Congress made such a 
limitation in the Individuals with Disabilities in Education Act, 20 
U.S.C. § 1415(e)(4)(C) where “no bonus or multiplier may be used 
in calculating fees awarded under this subsection.” Moreover, the 
limitation on marketplace factors sought by the City and amici was 
presented to Congress as proposed bills and amendments which 
were rejected. And, even if reference to legislative history is made, 
it demonstrates that it was Congress’ intent, object and design to 
adopt marketplace standards for calculating fee awards. In relying 
on the phrase “prevailing party” to limit the use of marketplace



6

factors in fees calculation, amici confuse the statutes’ entitlement 
standard with their fee calculation standard. That the phrase “pre­
vailing party” speaks to a party’s entitlement to fees has been 
repeatedly recognized in this Court’s fees jurisprudence. See Sec­
tion II, infra.

Nine circuits have accepted Justice O’Connor’s two-prong 
market test and applied it correctly. Nearly all have done so 
without difficulty, often on uncontradicted records. An upward 
adjustment for risk is not automatic under the test; numerous courts 
have found no need for risk enhancement or that the evidence 
submitted did not support enhancement. Justice O’Connor’s class- 
based assessment of risk has proven workable.

The City and amici do not dispute the marketplace basis 
of this Court’s prior attorney’s fees decisions, but simply 
reject the m arket’s treatm ent of risk. Their selective rejection 
of market principles defies the legal marketplace, the statu­
tory language, and well-established principles of market eco­
nomics. The City and am ici’s proposed per se rule prohibiting 
any risk enhancement has no legal or economic basis. See 
Section III, infra.

Because the district court, on an undisputed record, cor­
rectly held that an enhancement was available to compensate 
for contingent risk, this Court should affirm the district 
court’s award. See Section IV, infra.

ARGUM ENT

I.

A REASONABLE FEE FOR A CASE PROSECUTED ON 
A C O N T IN G E N T  F E E  BA SIS MAY IN C L U D E  AN 
A D JU ST M E N T  FO R  T H E C O N T IN G E N T  R ISK  OF 
LOSS

A. This C ou rt C onsistently  Has Accepted Legal M ar­
ketp lace P rincip les In  D eterm ining W hat Are R eason­
able Fees U nder Fee-Shifting S tatu tes

This Court has consistently relied on legal marketplace 
principles and practices in determining what are reasonable



7

attorney’s fees under fee-shifting statutes. In fact, in its fees 
jurisprudence, the Supreme Court has only relied on the 
m arketplace to effectuate congressional intent and determine 
a “reasonable” fee.

In Hensley  v. Eckerhart, the first case in which this Court 
provided guidelines for calculating a reasonable attorney’s fee 
pursuant to a m ajor fee-shifting statute, this Court adopted the 
tw elve factors set forth in Johnson  v. Georgia Highway 
Express, Inc., 488 F.2d 714 (5th Cir. 1974) as the foundation 
for calculating a reasonable fee. Hensley v. Eckerhart, 461 
U.S. 414, 429-30 n.3 (1983). These twelve factors derive 
directly from the American Bar Association Code of Profes­
sional Responsibility, originally promulgated in 1908 and 
operative today, as the factors used in the legal marketplace to 
calculate reasonable attorney’s fees. See, e.g., E. Cavanagh, 
Attorneys’ Fees in Antitrust Litigation: Making the System  
Fairer, 57 Fordham L. Rev. 51, 79 and n.199 (1988).

Moreover, Hensley applied the ABA factors with an eye 
to their use in the private marketplace:

Counsel for the prevailing party should make a 
good-faith effort to exclude from a fee request 
hours that are excessive, redundant, or otherwise 
unnecessary, just as a lawyer in private practice 
ethically is obligated to exclude such hours from his 
fee submission.

Id. at 434. The Court then held that district courts must 
consider the reasonable num ber of hours, the reasonable 
hourly rate, and “ also may consider other factors identified in 
Johnson, . . . ” and noted that the inquiry does not end with 
the lodestar:

There remain other considerations that may lead the 
district court to adjust the fee upward or downward, 
includ ing  the im portan t factor of the “ results 
obtained.”

Id. at n.9.
This Court again relied on the private market in Blum v. 

Stenson, 465 U.S. 886 (1984), which presented the question



8

of what is a reasonable hourly rate for attorney services under 
42 U.S.C. §1988. Petitioner in Blum  sought to have hourly 
rates set on a “cost-plus” basis. Id. at 892 n.6. The Solicitor 
General urged the Court to adopt a cost-related standard for 
non-profit legal services organizations. Id. at 892. A unani­
mous Court rejected these arguments and held that “ [t]he 
statute and legislative history establish that ‘reasonable fees’ 
under §1988 are to be calculated according to the prevailing 
market rates in the relevant community. . . . ” Id. at 894-95. 
These “prevailing market rates” are the rates that are “in line 
with those prevailing in the community for similar services by 
lawyers of reasonably comparable skill, experience, and repu­
tation.”2 Id. at 895 n . l l .

In City o f  Riverside v. Rivera, A l l  U.S. 561 (1986), the 
Court rejected a proposed rule that a reasonable fee be pro­
portional to the money damages recovered and affirmed an 
award for all hours reasonably expended at prevailing market 
rates. Although the dissent considered the award excessive, it 
recognized that market principles apply to the award of statu­
tory fees:

The analysis of whether the extraordinary number 
of hours put in by respondents’ attorneys in this 
case was “reasonable” must be made in light of both 
the traditional billing practices in the profession, 
and the fundamental principle that the award of a 
“ reasonable” attorney’s fee under §1988 means a 
fee that would have been deemed reasonable if 
billed to affluent plaintiffs by their own attorneys.

Id. at 591 (Rehnquist, J., dissenting).

The Court again adhered to legal marketplace principles 
in M issouri v. Jenkins, 491 U.S. 274 (1989). The issues there 
were whether: (1) an attorney’s fee can be enhanced to

2 The Blum decision also reaffirmed the Hensley holding that the 
lodestar fee could be enhanced, but reversed the enhancement awarded by 
the district court for lack of supporting evidence. Id. at 901-02.



9

account for delay in receipt of payment, (2) the work of 
paralegals and law clerks is a compensable part of a reason­
able attorney’s fee, and, (3) if  so, is compensation to be at 
prevailing market rates. In answering all these questions, the 
Court held that §1988 requires that market practices be fo l­
lowed:

The statute specifies a “reasonable” fee for the 
attorney’s work product. In determining how other 
elements of the attorney’s fee are to be calculated, 
we have consistently looked at the marketplace as 
one guide to what is “reasonable.”

Id. at 285-86.

On the issue of enhancement for delay, the majority 
stated, “ [o]ur cases have repeatedly stressed that attorney’s 
fees awarded under this statute are to be based on market 
rates for the services rendered” and held that compensation 
received years after the rendering of services is treated differ­
ently than compensation paid contemporaneously. Id. at 283.

On the paralegal/law  clerk compensation issues, the 
Court held that paralegal and law clerk time is to be included 
in reasonable attorney’s fees calculations and that market 
practices are to be followed in determining their amount:

If an attorney’s fee awarded under §1988 is to yield 
the same level of compensation that would be avail­
able from the market, the “ increasingly widespread 
custom of separately billing for the services of 
paralegals and law students who serve as clerks” 
Ramos v. Lamm, 713 F.2d 546, 558 (10th Cir. 1983), 
m ust be taken into account. . . . Thus, if  the prevail­
ing practice in a given community were to bill 
paralegal time separately at m arket rates, fees 
awarded the attorney at market rates for attorney 
time would not be fully compensatory if the court 
refused to compensate hours billed by paralegals or 
did so only at “cost.”

Id. at 286-87.



10

The Court held that §1988 only requires that market practices 
be followed, not that paralegals always be compensated sep­
arately at hourly rates:

Nothing in §1988 requires that the work of parale­
gals invariably be billed separately. If  it is the 
practice in the relevant market not to do so, or to 
bill the work of paralegals only at cost, that is all 
that §1988 requires.

Id. at 288. The Court rejected Petitioner’s claim that this 
would lead to a “windfall” for attorneys, or to separate billing 
for secretarial services and office supplies:

The answer to this question is, of course, that attor­
neys seeking fees under §1988 would have no basis 
fo r requesting  separa te  com pensation  o f such 
expenses unless this were the prevailing practice in 
the local community. The safeguard against the 
billing at a profit o f  secretarial services and paper 
clips is the discipline o f the market.

Id. at 287, n.9 (emphasis added).3

3 This Court also has accepted and endorsed legal marketplace 
practices in Blanchard v. Bergeron, 489 U.S. 87 (1989), and Venegas v. 
Mitchell, 495 U.S. 82 (1990). Both cases concern the relationship of 
percentage-based contingent fee agreements and §1988. Although neither 
case holds that the contingent fee percentage determines the reasonable 
statutory fee, both hold that the statute was designed to incorporate and 
enhance the incentives for attorneys to prosecute civil rights cases, not 
limit or restrict market practices and incentives. In Blanchard, Justice 
White, writing for the majority, recognized that the purpose of §1988’s 
fee provisions is “to encourage meritorious civil rights claims because of 
the benefits of such litigation for the named plaintiff and for society at 
large” and that using percentage-based fee agreements as a cap on fees 
“would create an artificial disincentive for an attorney who enters into a 
contingent fee agreement. . . . ” 489 U.S. at 95-96. In Venegas, Justice 
White, writing for a unanimous Court, made clear that a fee award under 
§1988 (which had included a 2.0 upward adjustment) did not limit the 

(Continued on following page)



11

In fact, in Department o f  Labor v. Triplett, 494 U.S. 715 
(1990), the Court expressly recognized that the availability of 
counsel will relate directly to the level of compensation, and 
that in certain markets, additional compensation -  or a risk 
premium -  will and should be reflected in that level of 
compensation. In Triplett, Petitioner challenged the Depart­
ment of L abor’s rule under the Black Lung Benefits Act 
prohibiting attorneys from recovering payments from their 
clients, claiming that it would lim it the availability of attor­
neys w illing to take contingent cases. However, under the 
statute, successful litigants were entitled to an award of “rea­
sonable attorney’s fees,” and the Departm ent’s own regulation 
perm itted enhancement to “permit consideration of the attor­
ney’s risk of going unpaid.” 494 U.S. at 726. Justice Scalia, in 
reasoning that was adopted by all nine Justices, held that the 
additional compensation for assuming the risk of nonpayment 
was consistent with market practices and the statutory provi­
sion of a “reasonable attorney’s fee” :

the existence in this country of a thriving contin­
gent-fee practice demonstrates that this risk can be 
compensated for -  so it comes down once again to 
the level of compensation.

Id.
The Court has therefore consistently adopted marketplace 

principles in its fees jurisprudence. It has accepted that the 
congressional purpose behind fee-shifting statutes is to pro­
vide incentives for com petent attorneys to enforce our 
nation’s civil rights and environmental statutes, has embraced 
the principles and practices of the relevant legal marketplace,

(Continued from previous page)
enforceability of a market-based contingent fee, despite the fact that the 
fee agreement resulted in a fee more than ten times respondent’s normal 
hourly rate. Again, the Court made clear: the statutory fee provision was 
not intended to limit market incentives for competent counsel to prosecute 
civil rights actions. Venegas, 495 U.S. at 86-88.



12

and has accepted contingency risk as part of that market and a 
perm issible component of a “reasonable attorney’s fee.”

B. Justice O ’C onnor’s Analysis of the Contingent
Adjustment in Delaware Valley II Is Consistent With
This Court’s Adherence To Market Principles

Following this long line of Supreme Court decisions 
adopting the market place analysis as the basis for determin­
ing a “reasonable attorney’s fee,” Justice O ’Connor in D ela­
ware Valley II ruled that an award of fees to a prevailing 
plaintiff may properly include an adjustment to compensate 
for the risk of loss if the relevant market reflects such an 
adjustment as to the class of litigation. 483 U.S. at 731-33. To 
avoid arbitrary and conflicting application of the contingency 
adjustment, Justice O ’Connor stated that contingency cases 
must be treated as a class, fee applicants bear the burden of 
proving the degree to which the relevant market compensates 
for risk, and enhancements should not be granted on the basis 
of the particular risks of the case.

Justice W hite’s plurality decision focuses on a different 
question. Rather than questioning whether a contingency 
adjustment may be part o f  a reasonable fee as determined by 
the market, the plurality asks whether the attorney may be 
awarded “separate com pensation,” 483 U.S. at 715, and 
whether Congress intended the risk of loss to be a basis for 
“ increasing an otherwise reasonable fee.” Id. at 723. The 
plurality opinion examines the difficulties in assessing a risk 
adjustment on a case-by-case basis and does not address 
whether the market can compensate for the risk of loss that is 
inherent in a class of litigation. The plurality, and indeed, all 
nine justices reject an individualized post hoc determination 
of the risks. 483 U.S. at 726-27, 731, 745.

The Dagues do not seek to overturn that judgment. 
Instead, they embrace Justice O ’Connor’s market-based anal­
ysis. By awarding a contingency enhancement based on the 
market treatm ent of a class of litigation, and awarding risk



13

adjustment only insofar as “necessary to bring the fee within 
the range that would attract competent counsel,” (Id. at 733), 
Justice O ’C onnor’s formulation avoids completely the diffi­
cult practical problems identified in Justice W hite’s plurality 
opinion and the possibility o f the award of a “windfall” fee. 
See Section III.D, infra.

II.
LEGISLATION PROVIDING FOR THE AWARD OF 
REASONABLE ATTORNEY’S FEES TO A PREVAILING 
PARTY INCORPORATES LEGAL MARKETPLACE  
FACTORS

A. The Language of the Statutes Demonstrate That Con­
gress Did Not Intend to Depart from Its Historic 
Reliance on the Market Model

When Congress enacted the environmental statutes at 
issue here, the phrase “reasonable attorney’s fees” for a pre­
vailing party had a well-established legislative and judicial 
meaning, which incorporated marketplace factors such as 
contingent risk. Under the rules of statutory construction, 
those phrases m ust be interpreted as they were in the securi­
ties and antitrust statutes previously enacted by Congress: to 
perm it a contingent risk adjustment in the appropriate case. 
Moreover, Congress has put the lim itation sought by the City 
and amici in other statutes, but not in the statutes presented 
here. Had Congress intended to prohibit the courts from 
considering m arketplace factors, it would have done so, as it 
has done in numerous other statutes.

Like many statutes enacted before them, the environmen­
tal statutes at issue herein provide for a “reasonable attorney’s 
fee” to the prevailing party. See 33 U.S.C. § 1365(d); 42 
U.S.C. §6972(e). The City and amici postulate that Congress 
abandoned its oft-placed reliance on the legal marketplace as 
a means of defining the amount of a “reasonable” fee to a 
prevailing party. To the contrary, the established canons 
o f  s ta tu to ry  c o n s tru c tio n  d em o n s tra te  th a t C ongress



14

incorporated m arketplace factors, such as adjustments for 
contingent risk, when it adopted the phrase “ reasonable attor­
ney’s fee” for the prevailing party.

“ [T]he purpose of a statute includes not only what it sets 
out to change, but what it resolves to leave alone.” West 
Virginia Univ. Hosp. v. Casey, 111 S. Ct. 1138, 1147 (1991). 
And, where a statute “contains a phrase that is unambiguous -  
that has a clearly accepted meaning in both legislative and 
judicial practice” the duty of the Court is to enforce the 
statute according to its terms. Id.

The phrase “reasonable attorney’s fee” for the prevailing party 
had a “clearly accepted meaning” at the time it was incorporated 
into the statutes at issue here -  a meaning that unquestionably 
included marketplace factors and anticipated adjustments for con­
tingent risk in the appropriate case. “Reasonable attorney’s fee” for 
the prevailing party plainly meant to Congress what it had plainly 
meant in the marketplace: that the risks of contingent representa­
tion may require special compensation.

It is a fundamental rule of statutory construction that 
words or phrases in a provision that were used in other 
statutes pertaining to the same subject matter will be con­
strued in the same sense. M arks v. United States, 161 U.S. 
297, 302-03 (1896); 2A Sutherland Statutory Construction, 
§51.02 (5th ed. 1992). The phrase “reasonable attorney’s fee” 
for a prevailing party occurs in a number of antitrust and 
securities statutes that were enacted prior to the environmen­
tal statutes at issue here.4 This Court and Congress have 
stated that these various fee-shifting statutes are to be inter­
preted “in pari m ateria."5

4 The Clean Water Act was enacted in 1972, and Congress passed 
the Resource Conservation and Recovery Act in 1976. The Civil Rights 
Attorneys’ Fees Awards Act, 42 U.S.C. §1988, which also provides for 
“reasonable attorney’s fees,” was also enacted in 1976.

5 See, e.g., Pennsylvania v. Delaware Valley Citizen’s Council for 
Clean Air, 478 U.S. 556, 559 (1986) (Delaware Valley /); Crawford 
Fitting Co. v. J.T. Gibbons, Inc., 482 U.S. 437, 445 (1987).



15

One o f the earliest prevailing party statutes to use the 
phrase “reasonable attorney’s fee” was the Clayton Act of 
1914, 15 U.S.C. §15, That phrase also is in the Securities Act 
of 1933, 15 U.S.C. §77k(e), and the Securities Exchange Act 
of 1934, 15 U.S.C. §78i(e), r(a), and u(h)(7)(A). By the mid 
1970s, when §1988 and the environm ental statutes were 
enacted, the phrase “reasonable attorney’s fee” repeatedly had 
been interpreted to include marketplace factors, such as the 
contingent nature of the case.6

6 See, e.g., Cherner v. Transitron Electronic Corp., 221 ESupp. 55, 
61 (D.Mass. 1963), modified on other grounds, Green v. Transitron 
Electronic Corp., 326 F.2d 492, 496-97 (1st Cir. 1964) (antitrust; contin­
gency enhancement awarded because “[n]o one expects a lawyer whose 
compensation is contingent upon his success to charge, when successful, 
as little as he would charge a client who in advance had agreed to pay for 
his services, regardless of success.”); Steinberg v. Hardy, 93 F.Supp. 873 
(D.Conn. 1950) (securities; contingency enhancement awarded, noting 
that “actions, even when well-founded, will seldom be brought unless 
counsel can be found” on a contingent basis and that “obviously a retainer 
on a contingent basis is distinctly less attractive” than a guaranteed hourly 
rate); City of Detroit v. Grinnell Corp., 495 F.2d 448, 471 (2nd Cir. 1974) 
(antitrust; risk enhancement available because “despite the most vigorous 
and competent of efforts, success [in litigation] is never guaranteed”); 
Lindy Bros. Builders, Inc. v. American Radiator & Standard Corp., 487 
F.2d 161, 168 (3rd Cir. 1973) (antitrust; lodestar may be increased to 
reflect contingent nature of case); Blank v. Talley Indus., Inc., 390 F.Supp. 
1, 5 (S.D.N.Y. 1975) (antitrust; $1.4 million fee based in part on contin­
gent risk); In re Coordinated Pretrial Proceedings, Etc., 410 F.Supp. 680, 
91 (D. Minn. 1975) (antitrust; enhancements awarded to “take into 
consideration the contingent nature of this litigation”); In re Gypsum 
Cases, 386 F.Supp. 959, 67 (N.D. Cal. 1974), ajf’d, 565 F.2d 1123 (9th 
Cir. 1977) (antitrust; enhancements awarded for contingent risk); Colson 
v. Hilton Hotels Corp., 59 F.R.D. 324, 326 (N.D. 111. 1973) (antitrust; 
court gave “great weight” to fact that contingent case “ought to yield a 
greater degree of compensation upon successful prosecution of the 

(Continued on following page)



16

Legislative language is interpreted with the presumption 
that Congress had knowledge of the basic rules of statutory 
construction. M cNary v. Haitian Refugee Center, Inc., I l l  
S.Ct. 888, 898 (1991); Stainback v. Mo Hock Ke Lok Po, 336 
U.S. 368, 377-79 (1949). And legal terms in a statute, such as 
“reasonable attorney’s fee” for a prevailing party, are pre­
sumed to have been used in their legal sense. Standard Oil 
Co. v. United States, 221 U.S. 1 (1911); Bradley v. United 
States, 410 U.S. 605, 609 (1973).

Here, Congress was enacting the fee provisions against a 
legislative common law of remarkable consistency and conti­
nuity in which “reasonable attorney’s fee” for a prevailing 
party incorporated the marketplace model and, in appropriate 
cases, the contingent risk enhancement. Since legislative lan­
guage is interpreted with the assumption that the legislature 
was aware of existing statutes and judicial decisions, United

(Continued from previous page)
action”); McKittrick v. Gardner, 378 F.2d 872, 875 (4th Cir. 1967) (social 
securities disability benefits; “the contingency of compensation is highly 
relevant in the appraisal” of reasonable attorney’s fees within the 25% 
statutory maximum); Angoff v. Goldfine, 270 F.2d 185, 189 (1st Cir. 
1959) (securities; remanding fee award and directing lower court to 
consider contingent risk); Perlman v, Feldmann, 160 F.Supp. 310 
(D.Conn. 1958) (securities; giving “great weight” to contingent nature of 
case); In re Detroit Int’l Bridge Co., I l l  F.2d 235, 37 (6th Cir. 1940) 
(bankruptcy reorganization under securities laws which considers 
“whether the fee is absolute or contingent”). See also, In re Osofsky, 50 
F.2d 925, 27 (1931) (bankruptcy action; contingency enhancement 
awarded because “however much ingenuity and time attorneys may 
expend, they may not be able to get anything for the estate by their 
efforts.”); F.B. MacKinnon, Contingent Fees For Legal Services: A 
Report of the American Bar Foundation 26 (1964) (“As we have seen in 
civil suits for damages under antitrust legislation the claimant is awarded 
reasonable attorney’s fees if the suit is successful . . . The contingent 
factors, among others, is recognized by the courts in making the award.”).



17

States v. M onia, 317 U.S. 424, 427-30 (1943); F.C.C. v. 
American Broadcasting Co., Inc., 347 U.S. 284, 297 (1954), 
Congress’ use of the phrase “reasonable attorney’s fee” for a 
prevailing party must be interpreted to include the availability 
of a contingent risk enhancement.

If Congress meant to abandon its historic understanding 
of the phrase “reasonable attorney’s fee” for a prevailing 
party, it would have used different words when it legislated 
the statutes at issue here. As noted by Justice Thomas in 
United States v. Wilson, 60 U.S.L.W. 4244 (1992), it is a 
“ fam iliar maxim that, when Congress alters the words of a 
statute, it m ust intend to change the statu te’s meaning” (cit. 
omitted). By parity of reasoning, when Congress does not 
alter statutory language, its intent is to retain the fam iliar and 
accepted meaning. See West Virginia Univ. Hosp. v. Casey, 
111 S.Ct. 1138, 1147 (1991); 2A Sutherland Statutory Con­
struction, §45.12 (5th ed. 1992). Here, Congress did not alter 
the words o f the fee provision because it did not intend to 
change the well established meaning of “reasonable attorney’s 
fee.”

Thus, in West Virginia University Hosp. v. Casey, this 
Court examined congressional changes to the phrase “reason­
able attorney’s fee” for a prevailing party in a variety of 
statutes. A comparison of the statutes was proper because 
statutes are construed “to contain that permissible meaning 
which fits most logically and comfortably into the body of 
both previously and subsequently enacted law.” I l l  S.Ct. at 
1148. Because a number of statutes contained an express 
grant to a prevailing party of reasonable attorney’s fees plus 
expert witness fees, the Court held that the statutory usage 
indicated that expert fees were an item “in addition to attor­
ney’s fees.” Id. at 1142 (emphasis in original). The Court 
reasoned that Congress would not have engaged in “an inex­
plicable exercise in redundancy” by changing the language in 
some statutes. Id. at 1143.



18

The same comparison of congressional changes to the 
phrase “reasonable attorney’s fee” for a prevailing party dem­
onstrates that it is proper for courts to consider the mar­
ketplace factor of contingent risk, unless otherwise directed 
by Congress, When Congress enacted the Individuals with 
D isabilities in Education Act (“IDEA”) in 1986, it speci­
fically prohibited all bonuses or multipliers. In order to alter 
the usual meaning of the phrase “ reasonable attorneys’ fee” 
for a prevailing party, Congress specifically stated that “ [n]o 
bonus or m ultiplier may be used in calculating the fees 
awarded under this subsection.” 20 U.S.C. §1415(e)(4)(C). 
Similarly, when Congress passed the Antitrust Civil Process 
Act Amendments of 1976, the legislators focused consider­
able attention on the availability of contingent recoveries for 
private attorneys. As a consequence, both the House and 
Senate ultim ately agreed explicitly to prohibit private attor­
neys from collecting contingency fees unless the award is 
determined by a court. 15 U.S.C. §15g(l)(A )-(B).

Thus, had Congress intended to limit the courts’ discre­
tion when they calculate a prevailing party’s reasonable attor­
ney’s fee, it would have imposed express lim itations, as it has 
done in numerous other statutes.7

7 Slightly more than one-fifth of the fee provisions in the United 
States Code regulate or limit the prevailing party’s attorney’s fee in 
certain types of cases. See generally 1 M. Derfner and A. Wolf, Court 
Awarded Attorney Fees, §504 (1991); Walters v. National Ass’n of 
Radiation Survivors, 473 U.S. 305 (1985) (upholding 38 U.S.C. §3404(c), 
which limits to $10 the fee that may be paid an attorney or agent who 
represents a veteran); 28 U.S.C. §2412(d)(l)(A) (fee awards under the 
Equal Access to Justice Act “shall be based upon prevailing market 
rates . . . except that. . . attorney fees shall not be awarded in excess of 
$75 per hour . . . ); 42 U.S.C. §300aa-15(b) (fee awards under the 
National Vaccine Injury Compensation Act of 1986 limited to $30,000); 
28 U.S.C. §2678 (fees under Federal Tort Claims Act limited to 20% of 
administrative settlement; 25% of judgment or settlement); 42 U.S.C.

(Continued on following page)



19

In contrast to the lim itations in myriad fees provisions in 
the United States Code, Congress included no such wording 
in the environm ental and civil rights statutes. In the same year 
that Congress enacted the IDEA, 1986, Congress amended the 
Superfund law (CERCLA), 42 U.S.C. §§9601 et seq. to add a 
c itizens’ suit provision, which provided for “reasonable attor­
ney ’s fees,” 42 U.S.C. §9659(f), yet did not include the 
restrictive language found in the IDEA. The “reasonable 
attorney’s fees” provision in CERCLA is identical to that 
found in the CWA and RCRA. As Chief Justice Rehnquist 
aptly observed in Crawford Fitting Co., 482 U.S. at 442, “ [i]t 
is . . . clear that when Congress meant to set a lim it on fees, it 
knew how to do so.” The City seeks to have this Court 
disregard Congress’ selective use of lim iting language in 
other fees statutes. That result is impermissible, because such 
an interpretation would render Congress’ words “an inexpli­
cable exercise in redundancy.” West Virginia Univ. Hosp., I l l  
S.Ct. at 1143.

Congress not only knows how to lim it fee enhancements, 
but it has also rejected proposed legislation that attempted to 
do so. In 1982, Senator Hatch unsuccessfully proposed an 
amendment to §1988 which would have prohibited “awards 
based on contingency factors or m ultipliers.” S. 585, 97th 
Cong. 2d Sess. §722A(e) (1982). See Attorney’s Fees Awards: 
Hearings on S. 585 Before the Subcomm. on the Constitution 
o f  the Senate Comm, on the Judiciary, 97th Cong., 2d Sess. 13 
(1982). In addition, four bills were introduced which would 
have capped attorney hourly rates levied against government 
defendants at $75, and eliminated multipliers and bonuses 
under all federal prevailing party fee provisions. None of

(Continued from previous page)
406(b)(1) (fees under Social Security Act limited to 25% of award); 22 
U.S.C. §277d-21 (fees under American-Mexican Chamizal Convention 
Act of 1964 limited to 10%); 48 U.S.C. §1424c(f) (fees for claims 
regarding land under Organic Act of Guam limited to 5%); 50 U.S.C. 
App. §1985 (fees under Japanese-American Evacuation Claims Act of 
1948 limited to 10%).



20

these bills passed.8 See S. 2802, 98th Cong., 2d Sess. (1984); 
H.R. 5757, 98th Cong. 2d Sess. (1984); S. 1580, 99th Cong. 
1st Sess. (1985); and H.R. 3181, 99th Cong. 1st Sess. (1985). 
As recently as last year, an amendment was proposed as part 
of the Civil Rights Act of 1991, which would have limited a 
prevailing party’s attorney’s fees to 20% of the total award. 
137 Cong. Rec. S. 15338-39 (daily ed. Oct. 29, 1991).

The rejection of an amendment indicates that the legisla­
ture does not intend the law to include the provision embod­
ied in the rejected amendment. Lapina v. Williams, 232 U.S. 
78 (1914); United States v. Great N. R.R. Co., 287 U.S. 144, 
155 (1932). Thus, the numerous failed attempts to lim it the 
availability o f enhancements in the environmental and civil 
rights area demonstrate that a contingent risk enhancement 
may be available in appropriate cases.9

8 In advocating on behalf of the failed bills, the Department of 
Justice raised many of the same arguments it raises here. See The Legal 
Fee Equity Act [S.2802]: Hearing Before the Subcomm. on the Constitu­
tion of the Senate Judiciary Committee, 98th Cong., 2d. Sess., 38-41 
(1984) (comments and materials submitted by Deputy Attorney General 
Carol Dinkins that a prohibition against multipliers is required because 
multipliers subsidize losing cases, create needless litigation, and are 
difficult for the courts to administer); Legal Fees Equity Act [S.1580]: 
Hearing Before the Subcomm. on the Constitution of the Senate Judiciary 
Committee, 99th Cong. 1st Sess. 47-51 (1985) (comments and materials 
submitted by Deputy Attorney General Lowell Jensen making same 
arguments).

9 This is, moreover, consistent with Crawford Fitting Co., 482 U.S. 
437 and West Virginia Univ. Hosp., I l l  S.Ct. 1138, where the Court was 
examining the civil rights and antitrust fees provisions as well as a 
separate specific statute that governed the topic of expert fees, 28 U.S.C. 
§1821. The Court described 28 U.S.C. §1821 as a statute which “compre­
hensively regulated” the kinds of expenses “that a federal court may tax 
as costs against the losing party.” Crawford Fitting, 482 U.S. at 440. 
Applying the well-settled rule that a specific statute will control over a

(Continued on following page)



21

Under standard rules of statutory construction, the lan­
guage o f the statutes cannot be interpreted to embody any 
lim it on use o f the m arketplace factor of contingent risk in an 
appropriate case. Congress has imposed the lim itation sought 
by the City and amici, but not in the statutes at issue here. 
The City cannot now impute such lim itation in the absence of 
clear congressional intent.

B. The Legislative History Adopts Marketplace Stan­
dards For Calculating a “Reasonable Fee”

The legislative history readily demonstrates that Con­
gress adopted marketplace standards for determining a rea­
sonable fee. In enacting §1988, Congress cautioned that 
“ [ujnless the judicial remedy is full and complete, it will 
remain a meaningless right.” H.R. Rep. No. 1558, 94th Cong., 
2d Sess. 1 (1976) (“H.R. Rep.”). In light of this goal, Con­
gress gave ample instruction to the courts on how to calculate 
a “reasonable attorney’s fee,” repeatedly pointing to a market 
consideration of the contingent nature of a case.

First, “Congress directed that attorney’s fees be calcu­
lated according to standards currently in use under other fee- 
shifting statutes.” Blum v. Stenson, 465 U.S. at 893. As the 
Court noted, Blanchard v. Bergeron, 489 U.S. at 95, Congress 
“clearly” instructed the courts to treat fee calculations in the 
same m anner as other complex federal litigation fee petitions:

It is intended that the amount of fees awarded under 
[§1988] be governed by the same standards which 
prevail in other types of equally complex Federal 
litigation, such as antitrust cases.

(Continued from previous page)
general one, the Court held that the provisions of 28 U.S.C. §1821 limited 
expert fees to $30 per day unless the statutory language indicated 
otherwise. Here, there is no specific statute such as 28 U.S.C. §1821 and, 
more importantly, attempts to pass such a specific statute limiting fees 
have been expressly rejected by the Congress.



22

S. Rep. No. 1011, 94th Cong., 2d Sess. 6 (1976) (“S. Rep.”). 
See also H.R. Rep. at 8-9 (referring to antitrust cases and 
noting that “civil rights plaintiffs should not be singled out 
for different and less favorable treatm ent.”).

In fact, Congress made repeated reference to the back­
drop of established judicial standards that incorporated mar­
ket concepts, and it directed courts to follow those standards. 
Thus, Congress “intend[ed] that, at a minimum, existing jud i­
cial standards . . . should guide the courts.” H.R. Rep. at 8. 
Describing the “ reasonable attorney’s fees” provision as a 
“key feature,” Congress commented that “ [bjecause other 
statutes follow this approach, the courts are fam iliar with 
these terms and in fact have reviewed, examined, and inter­
preted them at some length.” H.R. Rep. at 6.

As noted above, for years prior to the passage of the 
CWA and RCRA, courts had routinely awarded fee enhance­
ments where appropriate under sim ilar fee-shifting statutes to 
account for contingent risk in various types of complex litiga­
tion. See cases cited in IIA, supra. Thus, the “existing judicial 
standards” which Congress intended to govern determinations 
of a reasonable attorney’s fee, and which the courts had 
already “reviewed, examined and interpreted at some length,” 
included adjustments for the risk premium.

Congress then instructed the courts that “ [i]n computing 
the fee, counsel for prevailing parties should be paid, as is 
traditional with attorneys compensated by a fee-paying client, 
‘for all time reasonably expended on a m atter.’ ” S. Rep. at 6 
[citations omitted]. It was, and is, traditional for attorneys to 
receive a higher rate of compensation from contingent fee­
paying clients. As amici admit, “ [fjree legal services confer a 
substantial benefit on a client. In exchange for that benefit, it 
is reasonable for the attorney to charge a fee to the client, if 
the case is won, that is greater than the fee [an hourly fee­



23

paying] client would be charged for the time expended.” Brief 
of D istrict o f Columbia at 11 [emphasis added].10

Similarly, it is “traditional” for the risk premium for 
contingent cases to be calculated separately, rather than to be 
subsumed in the lodestar. See, e.g., Declaration of Chester 
Kamin at \1 \  Declaration of Chesterfield Smith at f  10; Decla­
ration o f Steven M ayer at f  8; Declaration of Robert Weinberg 
at f3 . See M aterials lodged by Respondents.

Finally, Congress cited several cases as guideposts for 
courts to use in determining a reasonable fee. Both the House 
and Senate reports cite Johnson  v. Georgia Highway Express, 
Inc., 488 F.2d 714 (5th Cir. 1974), which grafted the long­
stan d in g  leg a l m arke t fac to rs  “ c o n sis ten t w ith those 
recommended by the American Bar A ssociation’s Code of

10 Courts also have recognized the legal market truism that, in 
contrast to cases taken with the expectation of a guaranteed hourly fee, 
contingent cases can, in some cases, compel a risk premium. See Lindy 
Bros. Builders, Inc. v. American Radiator & Standard Sanitary Corp., 487 
F.2d 161, 168 (3d Cir. 1973) (no one expects a lawyer who works on a 
contingent fee to charge as little as he would charge an hourly fee client); 
see also Jones v. Diamond, 636 F.2d 1364, 1382 (5th Cir.) (en banc), cert, 
dismissed, 453 U.S. 950 (1981) (“Lawyers who are to be compensated 
only in the event of victory expect and are entitled to be paid more when 
successful than those who are assured of compensation regardless of 
result”); Stanford Daily v. Zurcher, 64 F.R.D. 680, 685 (N.D. Cal. 1974), 
aff’d, 550 F.2d 464 (9th Cir. 1977), rev'd, 436 U.S. 547 (1978) (“the 
American Bar Association [has determined] that attorneys deserve higher 
compensation for contingent than for fixed fee work”).

Congress expressly approved the Lindy case when it enacted the fee- 
shifting provisions of the Toxic Substances Control Act, (“TSCA”) 15 
U.S.C. §§2618(d), 2619(c)(2), and 2620(b)(4)(C). Like the statutes at 
issue here, all three of TSCA’s provisions allow a court to award 
“reasonable fees for attorneys.” The legislative history cites Lindy as 
illustrative of the fact that the amount of a fee award “can be adjusted for 
factors including, inter alia, the contingent nature of the success.” See 
House Committee On Interstate and Foreign Commerce, 94th Cong., 2d 
Sess., Legislative History of the Toxic Substances Control Act 255-56 
(Comm. Print 1976).



24

Professional Responsibility” onto the process of setting a 
reasonable fee under Title V II’s fee-shifting provision. Id. at 
719. See S. Rep. at 6; H.R. Rep. at 8. These twelve ABA 
factors include consideration o f “whether the fee is fixed or 
contingent.” 11 As recognized by Justice W hite, “ [i]n many 
past cases considering the award o f attorney’s fees under 
§1988, we have turned our attention to [Johnson],” and the 
Johnson  contingency fee factor is “a factor” which “may aid 
in determining reasonableness.” Blanchard, 489 U.S. at 93. 
See, supra, at note 3.

In addition to adopting Johnson, Congress pointed to 
three cases where the fee standards were “correctly applied.” 
Blanchard, 489 U.S. 87, (examining cases cited in legislative 
history to determine Congressional intent). S. Rep. at 6. 
These three cases are Stanford Daily, 64 F.R.D. 680; Swann v. 
C h a r lo tte -M e c k le n b u rg  Bd. o f  E d u c ., 66 F .R .D . 483 
(W.D.N.C. 1975); and Davis v. County o f Los Angeles, 8 
Empl. Prac. Dec. \  9444 (C.D. Cal. 1974).

11 The City and amici concede that this factor is applicable to a fee 
calculation, but attempt to limit its import by saying that the factor only 
focuses on the existence of any contract for fees between the attorney and 
client. This distinction is without significance. A court must look at 
whether or not the attorney accepted the case on a contingent basis, 
because “when the plaintiff has agreed to pay its attorney, win or lose, the 
attorney has not assumed the risk of nonpayment and there is no occasion 
to adjust the lodestar fee because the case was a risky one.” Delaware 
Valley II, 483 U.S. at 716.

Similarly, the plurality in Delaware Valley II recognizes that the 
factor “suggests that the nature of the fee contract between the client and 
his attorney should be taken into account when determining a reasonable 
fee,” 483 U.S. at 723, but fails to conclude that a higher fee award might 
be warranted when the nature of the fee contract involves the risk of no 
recovery. There can be no question that, when Canon 13 of the ABA 
Canons of Professional Ethics was promulgated in 1908 and amended in 
1933, it provided that risk of loss may be a factor in determining the 
reasonable fee: “A contract for a contingent fee, where sanctioned by law, 
should be reasonable under all the circumstances of the case, including 
the risk and uncertainty of the compensation,. . . . ”



25

In approving these cases, Congress embraced a definition 
of reasonable attorney’s fee” that permits upward adjust­
ments for factors such as contingent risk. In Stanford Daily, 
the court first found 750 hours expended by plaintiffs reason­
able and compensable. 64 F.R.D. at 683. Next, the court 
allowed m arket-based “fixed-fee” hourly rates averaging $50 
per hour, which defendants conceded were reasonable. Id. at 
684-85. Finally, the court examined the fact that counsel 
prosecuted the case on a contingent basis, and adjusted the 
lodestar upward by approximately 27% to provide “full and 
fair com pensation” :

Federal court decisions generally reason that the 
amount o f any award o f attorneys’ fees should 
reflect any contingencies which stood between the 
attorneys and their deserved fee [citations omitted]. 
These decisions parallel the American Bar Associa­
tio n ’s determ ination that attorneys deserve higher 
com pensation for contingent than for fixed-fee 
work . . .

Federal courts’ failure to make contingency 
calculations in determining fees awards, in contrast, 
would discourage many attorneys from accepting 
pro bono publico cases by presenting them with the 
financially unacceptable “risk of wasting hours of 
work, overhead and expenses”. . . .

64 F.R.D. at 685 (citation omitted).

Similarly, in Swann, 64 F.R.D. at 484-86, the court held 
that a “ [pjertinent factorf] in fixing fees” includes whether 
the fee is “fixed or contingent.” Finally, the Davis court 
acknowledged there may sometimes be a need for upward 
adjustment of the lodestar, 8 Empl. Prac. Dec. H 9444 at 5048, 
and recognized that the district court’s “first hand observa­
tions” are important in determining a reasonable fee. Id. at 
5049 (citation omitted).

None of the cases Congress highlighted supports the kind 
of m arketplace intervention the City and amici advance. None



26

of the cases suggests that an upward adjustment of the lode­
star for factors such as contingent risk is prohibited. The 
legislative history is devoid of such market restraints. In fact, 
as this Court has noted, “P etitioner’s argument that the use of 
market rates violates congressional intent . . .  is flatly contra­
dicted by the legislative history of §1988.” Blum, 465 U.S. at 
894.

To the contrary, Congress explicitly has recognized that 
reasonable attorney’s fee awards under §1988 may include 
upward enhancements. As noted previously, the fee-shifting 
provision of the IDEA expressly prohibits the use of a “bonus 
or m ultiplier” in calculating “ reasonable attorney’s fees.” 20 
U.S.C. § 1415(e)(4)(B) & (C). In the Joint Conference Report, 
reprinted in 1986 U.S. Code Cong. & Ad. News 1807, 1808, 
the House and Senate Conferees noted that by prohibiting 
upward enhancements in the IDEA, Congress did “not intend 
in any way to diminish the applicability of interpretation by 
the U.S. Supreme Court regarding bonuses and multipliers to 
other statutes such as 42 U.S.C. §1988.”

C. Recognition of the Risk Premium Is Consistent With
The Design, Object and Policy of the Statutes

In determining the meaning of a statute, the Courts look 
not only to the particular statutory language, but to the design 
of the statute as a whole and to its object and policy. Pilot 
Life Ins. Co. v. Dedeaux, 481 U.S. 41 (1987). As stated above, 
Congress’ design in enacting these statutes was to follow the 
market model, and Congress’ object and policy was to pro­
vide citizens with meaningful access to the courts to vindicate 
their rights. Failure to recognize and account for contingent 
risk in determining “reasonable attorneys’ fees” would there­
fore contravene Congress’ express design, object and policy.

Congress made findings that a fee structure regulated by 
marketplace factors was necessary to accomplish its purposes 
in the civil rights and environmental statutes. As the court



27

recognized in Delaware Valley I, “ ‘[t]he effective enforce­
ment of Federal civil rights statutes depends largely on the 
efforts of private citizens,’ and unless reasonable attorney’s 
fees could be awarded for bringing these actions, Congress 
found that many legitim ate claims would not be redressed.” 
478 U.S. at 560, citing H.R. Rep. at l . 12 “The purpose of 
§1988 is to ensure effective access to the judicial process.” 
H en sley , 461 U .S . at 429. T hese  fac tu a l f in d in g s 13

12 The legislative history of §1988 echoes these objectives again 
and again: See S. Rep at 6 (“[§1988] provides the fee awards which are 
necessary if citizens are to be able to effectively secure compliance with 
these existing [civil rights] statutes); S. Rep. at 2 (“civil rights laws 
depend heavily upon private enforcement, and fee awards have proved an 
essential remedy if private citizens are to have a meaningful opportunity 
to vindicate the important Congressional policies which these laws con­
tain”); S. Rep. at 5 (“[i]n several hearing held over a period of years, the 
Committee has found that fee awards are essential if the Federal statutes 
to which [§1988] applies are to be fully enforced”); and S. Rep. at 6 (“[i]f 
our civil rights laws are not to become mere hollow pronouncements 
which the average citizen cannot enforce, we must maintain the tradi­
tionally effective remedy of fee shifting in these cases.”)

The legislative history also repeats the concern that poor people in 
particular have meaningful access to the courts to assert their rights: See, 
e.g., S. Rep. at 2 (“[i]n many cases arising under our civil rights laws, the 
citizen who must sue to enforce the law has little or no money with which 
to hire a lawyer”); H.R. Rep. at 1 (“[b]ecause a vast majority of the 
victims of civil rights violations cannot afford legal counsel, they are 
unable to present their cases to the courts”); H.R. Rep. at 3 (“private 
lawyers were refusing to take certain types of civil rights cases because 
the civil rights bar, already short of resources, could not afford to do 
so.”).

13 Congress made these findings based on many days of extensive 
testimony. See The Effect of Legal Fees on the Adequacy of Representa­
tion: Hearings Before the Subcomm. on Rep. of Citizen Interests of the 
Senate Judiciary Committee, 93d Cong., 1st Sess. (1973) and Awarding of 
Attorneys’ Fees: Hearings Before the Subcomm. on Courts, Civ. Liberties, 
and the Admin, o f Justice of the House Judiciary Committee, 94th Cong., 
1st Sess. (1975).



28

made by Congress are entitled to “a great deal o f deference.” 
Walters v. National A ss’n o f  Radiation Survivors, 473 U.S. at 
330 n.12 (1985).

The Delaware Valley II plurality postulated that “ [i]t may 
be that w ithout the promise o f risk enhancement some lawyers 
will decline to take cases; but we doubt that the bar in general 
will so often be unable to respond. . . . ” 483 U.S. at 727. 
However, Congress found otherwise and, in any event, has 
relied upon the application of the market in order to assure 
that the bar does respond. See Sections IIA and B, supra. In 
particular, Congress wanted to assure that the bar responded 
to victims o f violations of environmental and civil rights 
statutes because, unlike personal injury cases, these litigants 
“seek[j to vindicate important civil and constitutional rights 
that cannot be valued solely in monetary term s.” Blanchard, 
489 U.S. at 96.

Similarly, Congress enacted the CWA’s fee-shifting pro­
vision, 33 U.S.C. § 1365(d), because “it is important to pro­
vide that citizens can seek [court enforcem ent],” and noted 
that “in bringing legitim ate actions under this section citizens 
would be performing a public service and in such instances, 
the courts should award costs of litigation to such party.” S. 
Rep. No. 414, 92d Cong., 2d Sess. (1972), reprinted in 1972 
U.S. Code Cong. & Ad. News 3668 at 3746-47.14

Congress has “ instructed the courts to use the broadest 
and most effective remedies available to adhere to [these] 
goals,” S. Rep. at 3, and “the fee-shifting provision [is] ‘an 
integral part of the remedies necessary to obtain’ compliance 
with our statutory policies.” Evans v. Jeff. D., 475 U.S. 717, 
731 (1986). In Stanford Daily, 64 F.R.D. 680, the court noted 
that accounting for contingent risk in setting a reasonable fee

14 Congress enacted the fee-shifting provision of RCRA “[drawing] 
on the similar provisions of the Clean Air Act of 1970 and the [Clean 
Water Act].” Delaware Valley I also noted “the purposes behind both 
§304(d) [of the Clean Air Act] and §1988 are nearly identical.” 478 U.S. 
at 559.



29

serves C ongress’ purpose of providing meaningful and effec­
tive access to the courts:

[Contingent adjustments] help[] attract counsel to 
the enforcement of important constitutional princi­
ples and significant congressional policies which 
m ight otherwise go unrepresented. . . . From the 
pub lic’s standpoint, the contingent fee helps equal­
ize the access of rich, middle-class, and poor indi­
viduals to the courts by making attorney decisions 
concerning representation turn on an action’s merits 
rather than on the size of a c lien t’s income.

64 F.R.D. at 685.

A “reasonable attorney’s fee” must account for contin­
gent risk if  Congress’ object of providing meaningful and 
effective access is to be met. As one commentator stated, “the 
experience o f the marketplace indicates that lawyers generally 
will not provide legal representation on a contingent basis 
unless they receive a premium for taking that risk.” S. Berger, 
Court Awarded A ttorneys’ Fees: What Is "Reasonable”?, 126 
U.Pa.L.Rev. 281, 324-25 (1977). See also Legal Fees Equity 
Act [S.1580]: Hearings Before the Subcomm. on the Constitu­
tion o f  the Senate Judiciary Committee, 99th Cong., 1st Sess. 
289 (1985), Testimony of Philip Sunderland (“without mar­
ket-rate compensation and without the possibility of having 
contingent representation, it is not only economically infeas­
ible [to take on cases], . . .  it is economic suicide”).

In sum, interpreting the statutory language to allow for 
contingent adjustments is “ reasonable, consistent, and faithful 
to [the sta tu te’s] apparent purpose.” Blanchard, 489 U.S. at 
100 (Scalia, J., concurring). Failure to adhere to market



30

principles in determining a reasonable fee will result in a 
failure to follow Congress’ design, object and policy.15

D. Risk Adjustments Do Not Compensate Non-Prevailing
Parties

The Solicitor General contends that including a contin­
gency adjustment in a “reasonable” fee is contrary to the 
statute, because an adjustment would compensate non-pre­
vailing parties. The Solicitor General has provided no legisla­
tive history in support of this interpretation and, as discussed 
supra in Section II, Congress enacted the CWA and RCRA 
prevailing party fee provisions in view of many other prevail­
ing party fee statutes, pursuant to which contingency adjust­
ments had long been made.

In relying on the phrase “prevailing party” to lim it the 
calculation of fees, amici confuse two separate inquires. The 
prevailing party inquiry defines the types of parties entitled to

15 The Solicitor General argues that because the fee-shifting statute 
constitutes a limited waiver of sovereign immunity, the statute must be 
construed narrowly. Solicitor General’s Brief at 26, n. 24. This issue was 
raised in the City’s Petition for Certiorari, and was not accepted. More­
over, as this Court has held, “[t]he question is what Congress intended -  
not whether it manifested the clear affirmative intent . . .  to waive the 
sovereign’s immunity.” Missouri v. Jenkins, 491 U.S. 274, 282 (1989); 
Franchise Tax Board v. United States Postal Service, 467 U.S. 512, 521 
(1984) (“waiver of sovereign immunity is accomplished not by a ‘ritualis­
tic formula;’ ” and “can only be ascertained by reference to underlying 
congressional policy.”). Congress explicitly included government defen­
dants in the CWA and RCRA. See 33 U.S.C. §1362(5); 42 U.S.C. 
§6903(15). Similarly, Congress intended §1988 to apply equally to gov­
ernment and nongovernment defendants: “With respect to the awarding of 
fees to prevailing defendants, it should further be noted that governmental 
officials are frequently the defendants in cases brought under statutes 
covered by [§1988].” H.R. Rep. at 7. See also S. Rep. at 5. Indeed, 
Congress has rejected bills which would have limited governmental 
exposure in fee-shifting statutes in the manner the Solicitor General 
suggests. See pp. 19-20, supra.



31

a fee award, while the reasonable fee inquiry defines the 
proper calculation of the fee award.

This Court defined the term “prevailing party” in Texas 
State Teachers’ Assn. v. Garland Indep. School Dist., 489 
U.S. 782 (1989). Writing for a unanimous Court, Justice 
O ’Connor defined “prevailing party” as an entitlement, rather 
than a fee calculation term:

Where . . .  a change [in the legal relationship of the 
parties] has occurred, the degree o f the p lain tiff’s 
overall success goes to the reasonableness of the 
award under Hensley, not to the availability of a fee 
award vel non.

Id. at 793. The distinction between the entitlement and calcu­
lation standards was also noted by the Court in Hensley, 461 
U.S. 424.

[The prevailing party standard] is a generous for­
m ulation that brings the plaintiff only across the 
statutory threshold. It remains for the district court 
to determine what fee is ‘reasonable’.

461 U.S. at 433 .16

W here Congress has lim ited the calculation o f the 
amount o f fees, it has left the prevailing party standard intact. 
For example, although the IDEA prohibits risk enhancements, 
fees are  aw arded  “ to the  p a re n ts  or g uard ian  o f a

16 The legislative history confirms that the phrase “prevailing party” 
speaks to entitlement to, and not calculation of, a “reasonable attorney’s 
fee.” Both the House and Senate Reports cite Newman v. Piggie Park 
Enterprises, Inc., 390 U.S. 400, 402 (1968) for the proposition that “a 
prevailing plaintiff ‘should ordinarily recover an attorney’s fee unless 
special circumstances would render such an award unjust.’ ” H.R. Rep. at 
6; S. Rep. at 5. In fact, the House Report contains a separate section 
entitled “Prevailing Party,” which discusses at length the issue of whether 
and when a successful litigant is a prevailing party under the statute. The 
House Report contains a wholly separate section entitled “Reasonable 
Fees.” H.R. Rep. at 8-9.



32

child or youth with a disability who is the prevailing party.” 
20 U.S.C. 1415(e)(4)(B). If, as the amici argue, the phrase 
“prevailing party” prohibits risk adjustments, then Congress’ 
lim iting language is rendered an “inexplicable exercise in 
redundancy.” West Virginia Univ. Hosp., I l l  S.Ct. at 1143. As 
discussed supra at pp. 18-19, Congress used the lim iting 
language of the IDEA and other “prevailing party” statutes 
when it intended to alter the usual meaning of the fee provi­
sion .17

Even more simply, only prevailing parties receive pay­
ment. The Dagues are prevailing parties. In fact, there is 
nothing in the record to suggest that the Dagues, or any of 
their attorneys, have ever lost a case under a federal fee- 
shifting statute or that they ever w ill.18 W hat Respondents 
and their attorneys seek in this case is market-based compen­
sation for the risk they took in prosecuting this case on a 
contingent-fee basis, not the risk undertaken in some other 
case. The legal m arketplace compensates for this risk regard­
less of whether an attorney has ever previously litigated a 
case on a contingent-fee basis or will ever in the future, or 
whether the attorney has won ten contingent-fee cases in a 
row or lost ten in a row. Under Justice O ’Connor’s test, the 
risk premium is analyzed on a relevant market basis and 
applies only if necessary to attract competent counsel to such 
cases, not to pay any non-prevailing party.

17 Amici argue that the term “prevailing party” operates as a limita­
tion on reasonable fees. To the contrary, this Court has held that Con­
gress’ choice of that phrase was intended to broaden, not limit, the 
availability of fees so that both plaintiffs and defendants could be entitled 
to fees. Christiansburg Garment Co. v. EEOC, 434 U.S. 412, 415-16 
(1978). See also H.R. Rep. at 6 (under the term “prevailing party,” “either 
a prevailing plaintiff or prevailing defendant is eligible to receive an 
award of fees. Congress has not always been that generous.”)

18 If Messrs. Pearson and Bland had ever lost a case brought 
pursuant to a federal fee-shifting statute, the “parties” in that case would 
have received nothing from the fee award in this case.



33

M oreover, in a private contingent fee situation, an attor­
ney cannot charge one client for the work performed in 
another case for another c lien t.19 If the acceptance of a 
contingency enhancem ent in private litigation was for the 
purpose o f paying for other failed litigation efforts, contin­
gency fee arrangements would be unethical, if not illegal. 
Nevertheless, contingency fee arrangements have long been 
accepted as legal and ethical, see ABA Model Code if Profes­
sional Responsibility, EC 2-20 and DR 2-106(b)(8); ABA 
M odel Rules of Professional Conduct 1.5(c) (1983), and 
indeed have been approved by this Court in Venegas v. Mit- 
chall, 495 U.S. 82 (1990), and Blanchard v. Bergeron, 489 
U.S. 87 (1989). Thus, m odem jurisprudence recognizes that 
the contingency enhancement compensates for the risk of loss 
in that case, not actual or potential loss in other cases.20

Lastly, although the Solicitor General today argues that a 
risk adjustment is inconsistent with the “prevailing party” 
language o f the statute, that has not always been the inter­
pretation of the United States. In Blum  v. Stenson, the Solici­
tor General, in contending that a public interest attorney was 
not entitled to a risk adjustment to the lodestar fee, made the 
following concession:

Ordinarily, when a lawyer engaged in private prac­
tice agrees to represent a client on such terms he 
may have to forego fee-generating employment.

19 An attorney is prohibited from receiving a fee from someone 
other than the client, unless the client has knowledge and consent of the 
arrangement. See ABA Model Code of Professional Responsibility DR 
5-107(A); Model Rules of Professional Conduct, Rule 1.8(f) (1983).

20 Amicus District of Columbia cites Independent Fed’ n of Flight 
Attendants v. Zipes, 491 U.S. 754 (1989), for the proposition that fees 
cannot be assessed against intervenors, and seeks to extend Zipes to mean 
that contingency adjustments assess fees against parties not determined to 
be non-prevailing. The Zipes decision cannot be tortured in this fashion. 
In Zipes, the intervenors were not determined to be wrongdoers and 
plaintiffs did not prevail against them. Here, fees have been assessed only 
against the non-prevailing party in favor of the prevailing party.



34

Some adjustment in the hourly rate o f  compensation 
to reflect the greater risk o f  nonpayment as com­
pared to the private attorney’s normal practice may 
be reasonable in such cases.15

15The normal hourly rates charged by counsel engaged in 
private practice reflect the fact that the client is expected to 
pay the fee regardless of the outcome of the case. If recovery 
of fees depends on the client’s success, it may be necessary to 
allow a slightly higher hourly rate to induce lawyers engaged 
in private practice to undertake cases covered by Section 
1988.

Solicitor G eneral’s Brief at 21, Blum  v. Stenson, 465 U.S. 8S6 
(1984) (No. 81-1374) (emphases added). This interpretation 
of a comparable prevailing party statute is simply incom pat­
ible with the Solicitor G eneral’s current interpretation that a 
“prevailing party” statute may never permit an adjustment of 
the lodestar hourly rate to reflect the risk of loss.

I II .

TH E TEST SET FO RTH  BY JU ST IC E  O ’CONNOR IN 
D ELAW ARE V ALLEY I I  IS CO N SISTEN T W ITH  M AR­
K ET PR IN C IPL E S AND HAS PROVEN W ORKABLE

A. N early  AH C ourts  H ave A pplied Justice  O ’C o n n o r’s 
C oncurrence  C orrec tly

The Solicitor General correctly notes that nine circuits 
have followed and applied the market-based test set forth in 
Justice O ’C onnor’s Delaware Valley II concurring opinion.21 
Solicitor G eneral’s Brief at 11-12, n. 11. Nearly all courts 
have not only applied Justice O ’C onnor’s concurrence, but 
also applied it correctly. M ost courts following Delaware 21

21 The non-conforming circuits are the Second Circuit, in this case, 
and the District of Columbia Circuit in King v. Palmer, 950 F.2d 771 
(D.C. Cir. 1991).



35

Valley II  have relied on testimony of attorneys practicing in 
the relevant legal market to establish, or dispute, the dearth of 
counsel and m arket treatment of risk. In most cases, this 
testim ony was uncontradicted, fact-finding was simple and 
straight-forward, and an adjustment was made. In other cases, 
evidence supporting a risk enhancement was found to be 
insufficient to meet the Delaware Valley II test, or was suffi­
ciently impeached so that no adjustment was awarded. Only 
one circuit has found the fact-finding required by Delaware 
Valley II to be too difficult to adhere to; yet previous panels in 
that Circuit correctly applied Delaware Valley II. Compare 
King v. Palmer, 950 F.2d 771 (D.C. Cir. 1991) with McKenzie 
v. Kennickell, 875 F.2d 330 (D.C. Cir. 1989).

The Third Circuit follows Justice O ’Connor’s test, and 
recognizes that contingency is to be treated on a class basis. 
That circuit also rejected the notion that econometric studies 
to quantify the market are required, although it has noted that 
conclusory affidavits, without sufficient factual foundation, 
are not sufficient. Blum  v. Witco Chem. Corp., 888 F.2d 975, 
983 n.2 (3d Cir. 1989) (“Blum II”). See also Vargas v. Cal­
abrese, 750 F. Supp, 677 (D.N.J. 1990).22

The Fourth Circuit also follows Justice O ’Connor’s test 
in resolving requests for contingency adjustments. Spell v. 
M cDaniel, 824 F.2d 1380, 1403-05 (4th Cir. 1987). Enhance­
ments have not necessarily been awarded in all cases. Rather, 
where defendants demonstrate that there is an ample supply of 
attorneys willing to prosecute contingent cases without an 
upward adjustm ent, contingency enhancements have been 
denied. See Duke v. Uniroyal, Inc., 743 F. Supp. 1218,

22 Thus, Blum II clarified earlier Third Circuit decisions. See Blum 
v. Witco Chem. Corp., 829 F.2d 367, 380 (3d Cir. 1987) (Blum I) 
(requesting “expert testimony from someone familiar with the economics 
of the legal profession.”) and Student Public Interest Research Group v. 
AT&T Bell Laboratories, 842 F.2d 1436, 1452 (3d Cir. 1988).



36

1226 (E.D.N.C. 1990), a ff’d in part and rev’d in part on other 
grounds, 928 F.2d 1413 (4th Cir. 1991).

Before the Fifth C ircuit will approve a contingency 
enhancement, there must be evidence in the record and speci­
fic findings by the trial court justifying the conclusion that 
contingency cases are compensated more highly in the private 
market than other cases and that enhancements are necessary 
to induce competent counsel to take such cases. Leroy v. City 
o f Houston, 831 F.2d 576 (5th Cir. 1987), cert, denied, 486 
U.S. 1008 (1988). In reversing and rem anding a d istrict 
court’s denial of a contingency premium for failure to make 
proper findings, the Fifth Circuit stated:

Justice O ’C onnor’s instructions in Delaware Valley 
II  are explicit: the district court m ust consider 
whether a contingency enhancement would have 
been necessary to induce competent counsel to 
accept such cases at the time the case was under­
taken and whether contingency cases as a class were 
treated differently from noncontingency cases.

Islamic Center o f  M ississippi Inc. v. Starkville, 876 F.2d 465, 
472 (5th Cir. 1989).

Similarly, the Sixth Circuit, applying Justice O ’C onnor’s 
test, rem anded a district court’s award of a contingency 
enhancement because the court did not make specific findings 
of fact as to the amount and necessity of a risk adjustment. 
Conklin v. Lovely, 834 F.2d 543, 553-54 (6th Cir. 1987).

„ The Seventh Circuit has clearly adopted Justice O ’Con­
n o r’s test for awarding contingent risk enhancements in cases 
where the evidence shows that, without the enhancement, 
plaintiffs would have faced substantial difficulties in finding 
counsel in the local or other relevant market and that the 
relevant m arket com pensates for contingent risk. King  v. 
Board o f Regents, 748 F. Supp. 686, 692-93 (E.D. Wis. 
1990).23 On the o ther hand, the d istrict courts have not

23 See also, Skelton v. General Motors Corp., 860 F.2d 250, 254 n. 3 
(7th Cir. 1988), cert, denied, 493 U.S. 810 (1989); Soto v. Adams Elevator 
Equip. Co., 941 F.2d 543, 553 (7th Cir. 1991).



37

awarded contingency adjustments where the evidence was 
insufficient to satisfy the Delaware Valley II test. Wolf v. 
Planned Property M anagement, 735 F. Supp. 882, 887 (N.D. 
111. 1990); Leigh  v. Engle, 714 F. Supp. 1465, 1475-76 (N.D. 
111. 1989).

The Eighth Circuit recently found that a plaintiff met the 
Delaware Valley II test based on “undisputed evidence” that 
very few attorneys were available to prosecute employment 
discrim ination and civil rights cases in the St. Louis M etro­
politan area and that a contingency enhancement was neces­
sary to attract counsel to such cases. M orris v. American N at’l 
Can Corp., 952 F.2d 200, 205-07 (8th Cir. 1991). However, in 
cases  w here  the  reco rd  fa iled  to e s ta b lish  tha t the 
unavailability  of a risk enhancem ent would have caused 
plain tiff substantial difficulty in locating competent counsel, 
the Eighth Circuit has denied a contingency enhancement. 
Hendrickson  v. Branstad, 934 F.2d 158, 163 (8th Cir. 1991).

The Ninth Circuit has applied the Delaware Valley II test 
correctly in a variety o f cases. In Fadhl v. City o f San 
Francisco, 859 F.2d 649 (9th Cir. 1988), the Ninth Circuit 
affirmed a contingency enhancement based on uncontradicted 
testimony that the legal marketplace, defined as Title VII 
cases in the San Francisco Bay Area, required an enhance­
ment for attorneys to accept such cases on a contingent fee 
basis. Id. at 650-51. Likewise, in Hasbrouck v. Texaco, Inc., 
879 F.2d 632 (9th Cir. 1989), an antitrust case, the Ninth 
Circuit affirmed a contingency enhancement under the Dela­
ware Valley II test, based on uncontradicted testimony from 
antitrust counsel. Id. at 637. See also D’Emanuele v. M ont­
gomery Ward & Co., 904 F.2d 1379 (9th Cir. 1990).

The Tenth Circuit, in Smith v. Freeman, 921 F.2d 1120, 
1123 (10th Cir. 1990) refused to establish a per se rule 
requiring an enhancement in contingent cases. The Tenth 
Circuit has further directed its district courts to make specific 
findings of fact, pursuant to Delaware Valley II requirements,



38

before they conclude that a class o f contingency cases 
requires upward adjustment of the lodestar. W ulf v. City o f  
Wichita, 883 F.2d 842, 876 (10th Cir. 1989).

The Eleventh Circuit also holds that the propriety of 
contingency enhancements is governed by Justice O ’C onnor’s 
test and has affirmed enhancements where the evidence dem­
onstrates their necessity. Curry v. Contract Fabricators Profit 
Sharing Plan, 744 F.Supp. 1061, 1073 (M.D. Ala. 1988), 
a ff’d, 891 F.2d 842, 850 (11th Cir. 1990); M artin  v. Univ. o f  
South Alabama, 911 F.2d 604 , 611 (11th Cir. 1990). In Nor­
man v. Housing Auth., 836 F.2d 1292 (11th Cir. 1988), the 
Eleventh Circuit upheld the denial of contingency risk enhan­
cement, finding that “the record is absolutely devoid of any 
evidence that would suggest that enhancement over the rates 
requested is necessary to attract competent counsel into the 
field .” Id., at 1302, 1306.

Thus, almost without exception, the circuits have under­
stood and followed the market test set forth by Justice O ’Con­
nor in Delaware Valley II, have required specific evidence to 
meet the test, and have demonstrated no more difficulty 
discerning the m arket treatm ent of contingency than the 
courts have in determining m arket-based hourly rates for 
attorneys o f comparable skill and experience or determining 
how the relevant market compensates paralegals and law 
clerks.24 Claims by the City and amici that Justice O ’Con­
n o r’s concurrence has proven to be “unworkable” stand w ith­
ou t'em pirical support.

24 Congress, of course, invested the federal courts with far more 
complicated evaluations of market conditions in antitrust and securities 
cases. E. Cavanagh, Attorney’s Fees in Antitrust Litigation: Making the 
System Fairer, 57 Fordham L. Rev. 51, 70-71 (1988). No one is suggest­
ing that evaluating market treatment of rates, paralegals, and contingent 
risk presents even a shadow of the complexity of such cases.



39

B. As With Other Economic Markets, the Legal Mar­
ketplace Normally Provides a Risk Premium For 
Cases Taken on a Contingency-Fee Basis

1. C ontingency Fee Cases N orm ally Command 
Higher Fees than Fees for Work on Noncon­
tingency Matters

It is not surprising that most courts have determined that 
the legal m arketplace compensates contingency-fee cases dif­
ferently than hourly rate representation. In calculating the 
initial lodestar, most courts employ an hourly rate that is 
comparable to what is reasonably charged by attorneys with 
sim ilar skills and experience for noncontingent matters. See, 
e.g., Lindy Bros. Builders, Inc. v. Am. Radiator, Etc., 540 F.2d 
102, 117 (3d Cir. 1976); Hidle v. Geneva County Bd. o f  Educ., 
681 F.Supp. 752, 755 (M.D. Ala. 1988); In re Wicat Securities 
Litigation, 671 F.Supp. 726, 732-34 (D. Utah 1987). That rate 
alone may not adequately com pensate the attorney who 
accepts a case on the condition that he or she receive no 
payment for a losing effort.

A contingent fee must be higher than a fee for the 
same legal services paid as they are performed. The 
contingent fee compensates the lawyer not only for 
the legal services he renders but for the loan of 
those services. The interest rate on such a loan is 
high because the risk of default (the loss of the 
case, which cancels the debt of the client to the 
lawyer) is so much higher than that of conventional 
loans. . . .

R. Posner, Economic Analysis o f  Law  534 (3d ed. 1986). It is 
this distinction between contingency rates and non-contin­
gency rates that may, where the market so demands, provide a 
basis for an “upward adjustment” of, or a “risk premium” 
over, the lodestar calculation. See also Affidavit of Richard 
Posner (“ [a]n award limited to normal time charges [in an 
antitrust case] would, in my judgment, typically undercom­
pensate the lawyers for the Class”) at 00244; Affidavit of



40

Frank Easterbrook and Robert Sherwin (under the “market 
value approach to the calculation of fees” in civil rights cases, 
the value of the attorneys services may depend “on how the 
client promises to compensate the law yer”) at D-4.25

2. Contingency Enhancements in the Legal Mar­
ketplace Find Well-Established Parallels in Mod­
ern Economic Theory Regarding How Markets 
Operate

The “contingency adjustment” at issue before the Court 
is simply a specific example o f a core economic principle 
called “risk prem ium .” The concept of a risk premium to 
provide incentives to invest in more risky enterprises has 
existed since Adam Smith wrote The Wealth o f  Nations,26 and 
continues to provide vitality to well-accepted principles in 
m odem  economic theory.27

25 These affidavits are in the materials Respondents lodged with the 
Court.

26 In 1776, Smith discussed the relationship between the risk in 
succeeding in any particular profession and the market wages paid to that 
profession. Indeed, in discussing the risks inherent in the legal profession, 
Smith suggested that a 20-to-l enhancement over wages paid to more 
secure enterprises would be appropriate.

How extravagant soever the fees of counselors at law may 
.. sometimes appear, their real retribution is never equal to 

this. . . . The lottery of the law, therefore, is very far from 
being a perfectly fair lottery; and that, as well as many other 
liberal and honourable professions, are, in point of pecuniary 
gain, evidently under-recompenced.

Adam Smith, The Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations 106 
(Modem Library ed. 1937).

27 The concept of the risk premium in accepted modem economic 
theory is most recently embodied in the works of economist William 
Sharpe, who won the 1990 Nobel Prize for his work on the “Capital Asset 
Pricing Model.” See W. Sharpe, “Capital Asset Prices With and Without 
Negative Holdings” 46 Journal of Finance 489 (1991).



4 1

Today’s economic literature exploring various aspects of 
labor and investment m arkets28 regularly refer to and accept 
the well-established concept of the risk premium. The market 
will frequently reflect a higher rate of return for an uncertain 
enterprise or investm ent over a safe one.

3. Court-Awarded Contingency Enhancements are 
Nothing More Than the Minimum Risk Premium 
Required by the Legal Marketplace to Attract 
Counsel to Fee-Shifting Cases

Enhancem ents o f fee awards by district courts under the 
typical fee-shifting statute simply reflect that, in some mar­
kets, a premium over normal noncontingent hourly rates may 
be required to attract competent counsel. Rather than being a 
“windfall for attorneys” above and beyond what is already a 
“ reasonable attorney’s fee,” the contingency enhancement is a 
potential risk premium which the market may determine to be 
part of the reasonable fee. An award that fails to include a 
risk premium for a contingent case is not a reasonable fee, if 
the m arket compensates for this risk.

Amici contend that a contingency enhancement is not 
necessary because: (1) attorneys may bargain for a percentage 
of p lain tiffs’ damage recovery; (2) representation may be

28 See, e.g., R. Evans & R. Weinstein, Ranking Occupations as 
Risky Income Prospects, 35 Indus. & Lab. Rel. Rev. 252 (1982); A.G. 
King, Occupational Choice, Risk Aversion, and Wealth, 27 Indus. & Lab. 
Rel. Rev. 586 (1972); R. Posner, Economic Analysis of Law, at 405-410. 
See also R. Posner, Law and the Theory of Finance: Some Intersections 
54 Geo. Wash. L. Rev. 159, 161 n.5 (1986) (“The higher expected return 
for riskier investments is a central empirical finding in the finance 
literature”) (citations omitted). One would never expect the market to 
reflect the value of a Federal Treasury Bill to be the same for volatile 
common stocks. If the expected returns were the same, no investor would 
purchase the stocks with their concomitant risk of loss. Thus, the risk 
premium is the price that the market uses to call forth an adequate supply 
of investors to undertake riskier investments.



42

secured through voluntary or pro bono efforts; or (3) liability 
is sometimes a sure thing. The last argument is simply a claim 
that, in certain classes of cases, there is no risk in assuming a 
contingent case. If this is so, the plaintiff will be unable to 
prove that the market in that type o f litigation commands a 
premium for the contingent case, and no premium will be 
awarded.

Contentions (1) and (2), however, simply reject the m ar­
ket-based approach to determining a reasonable attorneys’ 
fee. The use o f percentage recovery or pro bono efforts to 
provide representation to plaintiffs in certain types o f litiga­
tion, as well as compelling counsel to represent unpopular 
clients, are alternatives to the fee-shifting statutes, alterna­
tives of which Congress was clearly aware when it passed the 
fee-shifting provisions. See note 13 supra. In no way does the 
availability o f some lim ited representation through other 
means diminish the fact that, in many legal marketplaces, a 
risk enhancer is necessary to attract competent counsel.29

29 The Solicitor General also contends that a sufficient number of 
unemployed or underemployed attorneys are available to prosecute fed­
eral fee-shifting cases, and that no risk enhancement is therefore neces­
sary. There is no evidence in the legislative history that Congress 
intended that important federal policies be enforced primarily by unem­
ployed or underemployed attorneys. Effective enforcement requires pro­
viding plaintiffs with lawyers comparable in quality to those representing 
defendants. Moreover, justifying a “public interest discount” on the 
ground that some attorneys may have charitable intentions “invokes the 
interests of the disadvantaged to justify a policy contrary to their inter­
ests.” S. Berger, 126 U. Pa. L. Rev. at 312.

The “public interest discount” suffers from yet another faulty 
premise. Statutory fee provisions are not enacted for the 
benefit of lawyers; rather, they are enacted for the benefit of 
the class of persons protected by the statutes. Reducing the 
fees awarded on the ground that lawyers should be inspired 
by their sense of civic responsibility reduces the economic 

(Continued on following page)



43

C. The City and Amici Seek a Radical Departure from
Basic Marketplace Principles

The City and amici do not dispute the marketplace basis 
o f this C ourt’s prior fees decisions. In fact, they acknowledge 
it. See Wash. Legal Found.’s Brief at 8-9: “All nine justices 
[in Delaware Valley II] appear to [agree] that any contingency 
enhancem ent should focus primarily on market-wide condi­
tions. . . . ” M oreover, the City and amici do not dispute the 
applicability o f legal marketplace practices with regard to 
reasonable hourly rates, reasonable number of hours, and 
compensation for paralegals. Despite these admissions, they 
turn their backs on market practices regarding contingent risk. 
This selective  acceptance of market treatment of reasonable­
ness is contradicted by this Court’s fees jurisprudence, the 
text o f fee-shifting statutes, and legislative history regarding 
reasonable fees. See, Sections I, II.A and II.B, supra.

The City, with no supporting evidence, ignores market 
practices regarding contingent risk and baldly asserts that the 
reasonable hourly rate used in the lodestar calculation “neces­
sarily reflects contingency considerations.” Pet. Brief at 18. 
Nowhere does the City explain how a market hourly rate 
includes a contingency adjustment. See p. 23, supra.

The difference between an hourly rate and contingent fee 
engagem ent can be illustrated as follows. In one case, an 
attorney is hired at his or her normal hourly rate. The client 
agrees to pay hourly fees and all costs, including litigation 
expenses as billed on a monthly basis, win, lose or draw. The 
attorney receives payment on a monthly basis for 3,000 hours 
of time over a seven year period; the client also pays $80,000 
in costs and expert fees.

(Continued from previous page) 
attractiveness of such cases, thereby restricting the supply of 
legal resources made available. . . .

Id. at 312-315 (emphasis added).



44

In another case, an attorney receives no payment for 
seven years, during which time 3,000 hours and $80,000 in 
costs and expert fees are expended. The attorney has a right to 
be paid only if he or she prevails in the case. A losing case 
will cost the attorney the value of the time and expenses, 
because the client is incapable of paying costs. The case is 
successful; the client prevails. The client, however, does not 
meekly pay the attorney’s bill after seven years of work. 
Instead, the client disputes nearly all parts of the attorney’s 
fee and cost bill, and the attorney is forced to file a motion 
with the court, and defend an appeal, in order to be paid for 
the work and the underlying costs. The attorney earns no 
interest on the $80,000 advanced for costs.

The same fee would not be reasonable in both cases, nor 
would the legal marketplace treat these two types of represen­
tation the same. The City and amici would, however, treat 
them the same and would prohibit the courts from considering 
any evidence from the legal market. They fail to explain, 
however, why evidence of relevant market practices should be 
ignored or why market practices properly can be relied on to 
calculate a “reasonable” lodestar fee, but not a contingency 
adjustment.

D. The Objections Made by The City and Amici Regard­
ing the Need for and Operation of the Contingency 
Risk Factor Are Addressed by Justice O’Connor’s 
Two-Prong Test

Many of the City and am ici’s objections to Justice 
O ’C o n n o r’s tes t have been addressed . The rem ainder, 
addressed here, misunderstand her test, exaggerate the con­
cerns or are otherwise without merit.

First, the Solicitor General contends that the class-based 
m arket test fails to identify the “relevant m arket.” This 
alleged “difficulty,” however, is no different than the inquiry 
undertaken in connection with lodestar hourly rates, which 
requires courts to determine the market rate for the particular



45

type of case and geographic area. That relevant market anal­
ysis is properly left open for district courts. See H. Newberg, 
Attorney Fee Awards §4.14, at 142 (1986) (“Blum  deliberately 
adopted a flexible, undefined relevant community standard 
that leaves room for courts to adopt different geographical 
and litigation specialty approaches that best suit the particular 
circumstances involved”). See also Section III.E infra.

The Solicitor General next argues that Justice O ’Con­
n o r’s test is “unworkable” because (1) there is no incentive to 
control the size of the fee, and (2) if enhancements are 
“routinely” awarded, attorneys would decline to accept cases 
on a guaranteed, hourly rate basis. Again, Justice O ’Connor’s 
test addresses these concerns. If  the attorney declined repre­
sentation on a guaranteed, hourly rate basis, that attorney 
would not satisfy the test and obtain an enhancement.30 If the 
attorney billed more than a reasonable number of hours, this 
would be reduced as part of the lodestar calculation. Like­
wise, whether any particular hourly rate is discounted for 
“billing judgm ent” or poor results is again a market-based 
lodestar determ ination.31

30 The American Bar Association’s Standing Committee on Ethics 
and Professional Responsibility considers an attorney’s failure to offer a 
client an hourly rate contract before accepting a case on a contingent-fee 
basis to be a violation of professional ethics. ABA Standing Committee 
on Ethics and Professional Responsibility Informal Opinion, 86-1521 
“Offering Alternatives to Contingent Fees” (1986).

31 The notion that the contingent fee attorney has an incentive to 
unnecessarily increase hours defies common sense. The risk of receiving 
no compensation is enough incentive to expend only those hours reason­
ably necessary to win the case. See Stanford Daily v. Zurcher, 64 F.R.D. 
680, 683 (N.D. Cal. 1974) (“plaintiffs’ attorneys, who had no assurance 
that attorneys’ fees would eventually be granted, had incentive to mini­
mize rather than maximize the amount of time spent on the case”). 
Moreover, an increased expenditure of time will not decrease the risk 
inherent in a class of litigation. By analogy, if an investor is offered an 
investment stock that has a 50% chance of an attractive return and a 50%

(Continued on following page)



46

The Solicitor General also argues that Justice O ’C onnor’s 
test requires a “particularized” factual inquiry into the indi­
vidual p la in tiff’s “ actual difficulties” in retaining counsel 
rather than the general shortage of attorneys for types of 
cases. In the next breath, he acknowledges that the O ’Connor 
concurrence expressly prohibits the particularized assessment 
o f risk. In fact, the courts correctly have focused on the 
general dearth of counsel for certain types of cases, not the 
difficulty any particular plaintiff had in finding counsel. See, 
e.g., M orris v. Am erican Can Corp., 952 F.2d 200, 205 
(1991); Spell v. M cDaniel, 824 F.2d at 1405; Hidle v. Geneva 
County Bd. o f  Educ., 681 F.Supp. 752, 751-58 (M.D. Ala. 
1988). M oreover, all nine justices in Delaware Valley II 
rejected a particularized inquiry. See pp. 12-13, above.

The Solicitor General then claims that Justice O ’Con­
n o r’s test is “unworkable” because it relies on “self-serving” 
affidavits. Affidavits in support of -  or in opposition to -  
contingency adjustments are no more “self-serving” than affi­
davits regarding reasonable hourly rates, the reasonable 
number o f hours, the quality of legal representation, or the 
“exceptional success” of the results achieved. If any particu­
lar testimony is biased, or without proper foundation, defen­
dants can point that out and/or submit counter-evidence. The 
trial courts can be relied upon to separate the real from the 
imagined. Indeed, as this Court has stated, the district courts

(Continued from previous page)
chance of total loss, he or she may be willing to purchase 50 or 100 
shares, but will hardly be willing to risk all of his or her assets in that 
same stock. And, regardless of the size of the investment, the 50-50 risk 
always remains the same. Thus, while the attorney who is paid for all 
hours worked, win or lose, may have an incentive to increase the hours 
billed, an attorney paid on a contingent basis (and who will have to run 
the gauntlet of a federal court fee application) will have every incentive to 
moderate the time/cost investment, due to the uncertainty of payment.



47

have “superior understanding” of such factual m atters.32 
Hensley, 461 U.S. at 437.

The W ashington Legal Foundation claims that Justice 
O ’C onnor’s test would defeat the “rare and exceptional cir­
cum stances” rule. No Supreme Court case, including Dela­
ware Valley II, has applied the “rare and exceptional” test to 
con tingency  ad justm ents. Were contingency adjustm ents 
available only in “rare and exceptional” cases, it would be 
contrary to legal m arketplace treatment of risk, and would 
require a particularized, post-hoc  analysis to determine if  the 
risk undertaken in that case greatly exceeded normal risk 
levels.

This amicus argues that accounting for contingent risk 
will result in “nonm eritorious civil rights and environmental 
law com plaints.” Wash. Legal Found.’s Brief at 18. Congress 
responded to this concern by providing fees for prevailing 
defendants where the case was “frivolous, unreasonable, or 
without foundation,” Christiansburg Garment Co. v. EEOC, 
434 U.S. 412, 421 (1978), not by lim iting the calculation of 
an otherwise reasonable fee as it has done in numerous other 
statutes. See Section II.A.

The amicus further contends that if contingency can be 
reflected in a fee, “ [tjhere is no lim iting principle” on contin­
gency adjustments. That obviously has not happened under 
Delaware Valley II. See Section III.A. Moreover, it could not

32 The level of proof of unavailability of counsel required in 
Department of Labor v. Triplett, 494 U.S. 715 (1990), is not applicable 
here. In Triplett, the anecdotal evidence submitted sought to attack the 
constitutionality of the implementation of the Black Lung Benefit Act, 30 
U.S.C. §§901 et. seq. This Court noted “the heavy presumption of 
constitutionality” and held, as it had in Walters v. National Assn, of 
Radiation Survivors, 473 U.S. 305 (1985), that anyone challenging the 
law on constitutional grounds had to make “an extraordinarily strong 
showing . . .  to warrant a holding that the fee limitation denies claimants 
due process of law.” Triplett, 494 U.S. at 722.



48

happen. The lim iting principle” o f the O ’Connor concur­
rence is the class-based assessment o f risk and the directive 
that any contingency enhancem ent be no “more than neces­
sary to bring the fee within the range that would attract 
competent counsel.” Delaware Valley II, at 733.

E. Determination of the Appropriate Market-Based Con­
tingency Adjustment is a Judicial, Not Legislative,
Task

The Solicitor General and the D istrict o f Columbia sug­
gest that Congress should sit as a legislative price control 
board that directs the appropriate payment for legal services 
on a nationwide basis. Solicitor G eneral’s Brief at 25-26; 
D istrict o f Colum bia’s Brief at 24-26. These amici assert that 
Congress is better able to direct a fair payment for legal work 
involving compensation for risk than the courts are able to 
evaluate how the free market compensates such work, despite 
this Court s emphasis that the district court has “superior 
understanding” o f such factual matters. Hensley, 461 U S at 
437.

The short answer is that when Congress decides to inter­
vene with the market and set the level of attorney compensa­
tion, it says so in the statute. See supra  at pp. 17-19. 
However, where Congress does not impose such restrictions, 
it relies upon the courts to evaluate the operation of the legal 
marketplace. The market for legal services is not monolithic: 
it is not a uniform, national market that applies in the same 
m anner to all the various types of cases brought pursuant to 
statutes that contain fees provisions. Nor is the free market 
static. D istrict courts are well suited to making specific fact­
finding decisions about the operation of the legal market at 
specific locations and at particular times with respect to a 
certain type of case, just as courts are relied upon to make 
other complex decisions regarding the market. See note 24, 
supra.

The courts make these kinds of findings regarding hourly 
rates and other matters related to the determination of the 
lodestar. The City and amici do not, and cannot, contest this.



49

There is no basis for concluding that courts are able to 
determine some aspects of the market, but not the market for 
risk compensation.

IV.

TH E D IST R IC T  COURT PRO PERLY  EX ERCISED ITS 
D ISC R E T IO N  W H EN  IT  AWARDED AN EN H A N CE­
M EN T O F TH E LODESTAR FEE BASED UPON CON­
TIN G EN T RISK

The district court properly held that a “reasonable attor­
ney ’s fee” under the applicable federal fee-shifting statutes 
may include an enhancement of the lodestar fee to compen­
sate for contingent risk. App. I at 130-33. Based on the 
evidence submitted, the district court found that the Dagues 
were entitled to a 25% contingent risk enhancement. App. I at 
133. The Second Circuit agreed with the district court’s deter­
m ination that contingent risk may be taken into account in 
calculating a reasonable attorney’s fee. App. I at 35-37. It 
concluded that the district court’s award of a 25% enhance­
ment was supported by its findings and affirmed it. App. I at 
34-37. Because it was within the authority of the lower court 
to adjust the lodestar fee to compensate for contingent risk, 
the district court’s ruling should be affirmed.

The City criticizes the adequacy of the affidavits the 
Dagues submitted to support their enhancement request. How­
ever, the City did not raise the sufficiency of the evidence 
supporting the fee enhancement in its appeal to the Second 
C ircuit nor in its petition for certiorari. Moreover, this 
Court’s grant of certiorari does not encompass this inquiry. 
The C ourt’s order granting certiorari is limited to the issue of 
whether a court may, in determining a reasonable attorney’s 
fee under the environmental statutes, enhance the lodestar fee 
to account for contingent risk.33

33 The City urges this Court to remand the fee award to the district 
court not only to vacate the risk enhancement but also to reduce the 

(Continued on following page)



50

Even if  the issue were properly before this Court, this 
Court need not, and indeed should not, address it. Instead, the 
case should be remanded to the district court for reconsidera­
tion of the risk enhancem ent calculation, consistent with 
Justice O ’C onnor’s test. As discussed in Section III.E, supra, 
the district court is keenly fam iliar with the facts relevant to 
the inquiry. It is in the best position to evaluate the unique 
evidence of the local Burlington legal m arket’s treatm ent of 
contingent risk and the availability o f counsel to take complex 
cases such as this one.

CONCLUSION

Respondents request that this Court affirm the fee enhan­
cement for contingent risk awarded by the district court.
Guy T. Sapertein 
M ari M ayeda 
Barry Goldstein 
Jocelyn D. Larkin 
Donna Ryu 
Jeremy Friedman 
L inda M. Dardarian 
Saperstein, M ayeda, 

L arkin & Goldstein 
1300 Clay Street,

11th Floor 
Oakland, CA 94612 
(510) 763-9800

W illiam W. P earson*
M olloy, Jones & Donahue, P.C. 
33 North Stone Avenue,

Suite 2100
Tucson, Arizona 85701 
(602) 620-5520

*Counsel o f  Record fo r  
Respondents

(Continued from previous page)
lodestar figure. Pet. Brief at 24-26. The City argues that the results 
obtained in the litigation were limited and do not justify the lodestar 
amount, citing Hensley, 461 U.S. at 429. The district court rejected this 
same argument below, as did the Second Circuit. As stated above, 
certiorari was granted only on the issue of the availability of contingent 
risk enhancements. Accordingly, the issue of the propriety of the lodestar 
figure under Hensley is not before this Court.

Copyright notice

© NAACP Legal Defense and Educational Fund, Inc.

This collection and the tools to navigate it (the “Collection”) are available to the public for general educational and research purposes, as well as to preserve and contextualize the history of the content and materials it contains (the “Materials”). Like other archival collections, such as those found in libraries, LDF owns the physical source Materials that have been digitized for the Collection; however, LDF does not own the underlying copyright or other rights in all items and there are limits on how you can use the Materials. By accessing and using the Material, you acknowledge your agreement to the Terms. If you do not agree, please do not use the Materials.


Additional info

To the extent that LDF includes information about the Materials’ origins or ownership or provides summaries or transcripts of original source Materials, LDF does not warrant or guarantee the accuracy of such information, transcripts or summaries, and shall not be responsible for any inaccuracies.