Domino's Pizza, LLC v. McDonald Brief Amici Curiae in Support of Respondent
Public Court Documents
September 22, 2005

Cite this item
-
Brief Collection, LDF Court Filings. Docutel/Olivetti Corporation v. Finkel Respondent's Brief in Opposition to Petition for a Writ of Certiorari to the US Court of Appeals for the Fifth Circuit, 1987. e60b07fb-af9a-ee11-be36-6045bdeb8873. LDF Archives, Thurgood Marshall Institute. https://ldfrecollection.org/archives/archives-search/archives-item/32ed22be-bf63-4349-a6b5-724b4ea024d9/docutelolivetti-corporation-v-finkel-respondents-brief-in-opposition-to-petition-for-a-writ-of-certiorari-to-the-us-court-of-appeals-for-the-fifth-circuit. Accessed April 06, 2025.
Copied!
No. 87-303 In The Supreme Court of the United States October Term, 1987 ----------------o--------------- DOCUTEL/OLIVETTI CORPORATION, ING. C. OLI VETTI & C., S.p.A., CARLO DE BENEDETTI, EM METT R. DeMOSS, JR., SIMONE FUBINI, B. J. MEREDITH and ELSERINO M. PIOL, Petitioners, v. HANNAH FINKEL, Respondent. ----- — -— o------ ------ -—■ RESPONDENT’S BRIEF IN OPPOSITION TO PETITION FOR A WRIT OF CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE FIFTH CIRCUIT ----------------o---------------- O f Counsel: JULES BRODY STULL, STULL & BRODY 6 East 45th Street New York, New York 10017 (212) 687-7230 W . D. MASTERSON THEODORE C. ANDERSON KILGORE & KILGORE 2900 First RepublicBank Plaza 901 Main Street, LB-180 Dallas, Texas 75202 (214) 741-6781 Attorneys fo r Respondent COCKLE LAW BRIEF PRINTING CO., (800) 225-6964 or call collect (402) 342-2831 ROGER F. CLAXTON Counsel of Record 2900 First RepublicBank Plaza 901 Main Street, LB-180 Dallas, Texas 75202 (214) 741-6781 1 QUESTION PRESENTED Is a plaintiff class of investors which purchases se curities in an established market at a price artificially inflated by a scheme to defraud or course of business that operates as a fraud on investors, entitled to a presump tion of reliance in order to recover for securities fraud under Section 10(b) of the 1934 Act and Rule 10b-5(l) and (3) thereunder? 11 QUESTION PRESENTED ........................................... i TABLE OF AUTHORITIES ............................... ill STATEMENT OF THE C A S E ..................................... 2 STATEMENT OF F A C T S............................................. 3 REASONS FOR DENYING THE PETITION ........... 5 T. RESPONDENTS WERE ENTITLED TO A REBUTTABLE PRESUMPTION OF RE LIANCE UNDER THE FRAUD ON THE MARKET DOCTRINE ................................... 5 II. THE FRAUD ON THE MARKET DOC TRINE FURTHERS THE CLEAR IN TENT OF CONGRESS................................... 8 III. THIS COURT HAS PREVIOUSLY CON SIDERED THE INDIVIDUAL RELIANCE ISSUE IN THE SECURITIES FRAUD CONTEXT ........................................................ 16 IV. PETITIONERS DO NOT HAVE STAND ING TO ASSERT THE CONFLICT WITH IN THE CIRCUITS AS A REASON FOR THIS COURT TO GRANT CERTIORARI... 18 V. THIS CASE DIFFERS FROM BASIC VS. LEVINSON WHICH IS CURRENTLY BE FORE THIS COURT ...... 20 CONCLUSION ................................................................. 22 TABLE OF CONTENTS Page I l l Cases TABLE OF AUTHORITIES Page Affiliated Ute Citizens v. United States, 406 U.S. 128 (1972) ....................................... 16,17,18 Bateman. Eichler, Hill Richards, Inc. v. Berner, 472 U.S. 299 (1985) ............................... 12 Blackie v. Barrack, 524 F.2d 891 (9th Cir. 1975), cert, denied, 429 U.S. 816 (1976) ...6,10,11,19 Blue Chip Stamps v. Manor Drug Stores, 421 U.S. 723 (1975) ............................................... 10 Chemetron Corp. v. Business Funds. Inc., 718 F.2d 725 (5th Cir. 1983) ........ ....................... 16 Dorfman v. First Boston Corp., 62 F.R.D. 466 (E.D.Pa. 1974) ............. ................................. 18 Dupuy v. Dupmj, 551 F.2d 1005 (5th Cir. 1977), cert, denied, 434 U.S. 911 (1977) ............... 6 Finkel v. Do cut el/ Olivetti, 817 F.2d 356 (5th Cir. 1987) ............................................................ 6,7,8 Green v. Occidental, 541 F.2d 1335 (9th Cir. 1976) 15 Harris v. Union Electric Co., 787 F.2d 355 (8th Cir. 1986), cert, denied, No. 85-2036 (Oct. 6, 1986) ................................................................... 6 Herman do MacLean v. Huddleston, 459 U.S. 375 (1983) .............................................................. 15 In re LTV Securities Liliaation, 88 F.R.D. 134 (N.D. Texas 1980) .... 1.....................................7,13,15 Kardon v. National Gypsum, 69 F.Supp. 512 (E.D.Penn. 1946) .................................................. 9 Levinson v. Basic, 786 F.2d 741 (6th Cir. 1986), cert, granted, 107 S. Ct. 1284 (Feb. 23, 1987) (No. 86-279) ...............................................6,12,20,21 IV Lipton v. Documation, Inc., 734 F.2d 740 (11th Cir. 1984), cert, denied, 469 U.S. 1132 (1985) 6,10,19 Mills v. Electric Auto-Lite Co., 396 U.S. 375 (1970) .............................................. ......................16,17 Pansirer v. Wolf, 663 F.2d 365 (2d Cir. 1981), vacated as moot after cert, granted, 459 U.S. 1027 (1982) .................................................. 6 Peil v. Speiser, 806 F.2d 1154 (3d Cir. 1986) .......6,19 T.J. Raney d Sons, Inc. v. Fort Cobb, Okla homa Irrigation Fuel Authority, 717 F.2d 1330 (10th Cir. 1983), cert, denied, 465 U.S. 1026 (1984) ............................................................ 6 Rifhin v. Crow, 574 F.2d 256 (5th Cir. 1978) ....... 18 Ross v. A.H. Robins Co., 607 F.2d 545 (2d Cir. 1979), cert, denied, 446 U.S. 946 (1980) ...........6,16 Schlanger v. Four-Phase Systems, Inc., 555 F.Supp. 535 (S.D.N.Y. 1982) .............................. 11 SEC v. Texas Gulf Sulphur Co., 401 F.2d 833 (2d Cir. 1968) (en banc), cert, denied, 394 U.S. 976 (1969) .................................................... 10 Shores v. Sklar, 647 F.2d 462 (5th Cir. 1981) (en banc), cert, denied, 459 U.S. 1102 (1983) ...2,3,6 Valley Forge College v. Americans United, 454 U.S. 464 (1982) ............................................. 19 Vervaecke v. Chiles, Heider & Co., 578 F.2d 713 (8th Cir. 1978) ............................................... 18 TABLE OF AUTHORITIES—Continued Page S tatutes and R ules Section 10(b) of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934, 15 U.S.C. § 7Sj(b) ...2, 8, 9,10,15,16,17 Section 14(a) of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934, 15 U.S.C. § 78 (n) (1976) ................. 17 Section 18(a) of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934, 15 U.S.C. § 78(r) ............ ............. 15, 16 Section 20 of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934, 15 U.S.C. §78 (t) ......................................... 2 Securities and Exchange Commission Rule 10b-5, 17 C.F.R. § 240.1013-5 ..................... ....passim Rule 12(b)(6) Fed. F. Civ. P. ................................ 20 Rule 23(a) and (b) (3) Fed. R. Civ. P . .............2,12, 20 A rticles Black, Fraud on the Market: A Criticism of Dispensing with Reliance Requirements in Certain Open Market Transactions, 62 X.C.L. Rev. 435 (1984) ............................................ 9 A. Bromberg & L. Lowenfels, 1 Securities Fraud and Commodities Fraud, 2.2(110) at 2:13 (1986) ....................................................... 10 Easterbrook and Fischel, Mandatory Disclos ure and the Protection of Investors, 70 Ya. L.Rev. 669 (1984) .................................................. 12 Note, The Efficient Capital Market Hypoth esis, Economic Theory and the Regulation of the Securities Industry, 29 Stan. L. Rev. 1031 (1977) ...................................... 7 TABLE OF AUTHORITIES—Continued Page VI Fama, Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical Work, 25 J.Fin. 383 (1970) .............................................................. 7 Fiscliel, TJse of Modern Finance Theory in Se curities Fraud Cases Involving Actively Traded Securities, 38 Bus.L. 1 (1982) ...............7,14 Note, Fraud on the Market: An Emerging Theory of Recovery Under SEC Rule 10b-5, 50 Geo. Wash. L. Rev. 627 (1982) ...................... 9 Note, Fraud-on-the-Market Theory, 95 Harv. L.Rev. 1143 (1982) .............................................7, 9,13 H. Kripke, The SEC and Corporate Disclos ure at 14 (1979) .................................................. 7 Rapp, Rule 10b-5 and “ Fraud-on-the-Market” —Heavy Seas Meet Tranquil Shores, 39 Wash. & Lee L.Rev. 861 (1982) .......................... 9 M iscellaneous Testimony of Thomas G. Corcoran, Hearing on HR 7852 and HR 8720 before the House Committee on Interstate and Foreign Com merce, 73d Congress, 2d Sess., 115 (1934) ....... 10 Wall Street Journal, April 2, 1984 ........................5,15 TABLE OF AUTHORITIES—Continued Page No. 87-303 ---------------- o— _— .—---- In The Supreme Court ©f the United States October Term, 1987 —------------ o---------------- DOCUTEL/OLIVETTI CORPORATION, ING. C. OLI VETTI & C., S.p.A., CARLO DE BENEDETTI, EM METT R. DeMOSS, JR., SIMONE FUBINI, B. J. MEREDITH and ELSERINQ M. PIOL, v. Petitioners, HANNAH FINKEL, Respondent. ■o------------- RESPONDENT’S BRIEF IN OPPOSITION TO PETITION FOR A WRIT OF CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE FIFTH CIRCUIT ------------— o--------------- Respondent Hannah Finkel respectfully requests that the Court deny the Petition for Certiorari to the United States Court of Appeals for the Fifth Circuit (“ Petition” ) submitted by Docutel/Olivetti Corporation (“ Docutel” ) and several individuals (collectively the “ Defendants” ) to review a final judgment of the United States Court of 1 2 Appeals for the Fifth Circuit. The judgment appealed from (i) reversed the District Court’s Order granting Defendants/Petitioners’ Motion to Dismiss dismissing Plaintiff’s claims under 10b-5(l) and (3) of the Securities and Exchange Commission, and (ii) affirmed the District Court’s Order granting Defendants’ Motion to Dismiss Plaintiff’s claims under Rule 10b-5(2) of the Securities and Exchange Commission. --------------------o— -—■— -—-— •• STATEMENT OF THE CASE Course of Proceedings and Disposition Below Plaintiff’s complaint arises under Sections 10(b) and 20 of the Securities and Exchange Act of 1934, 15 U.S.C. § 78(a), et seq. (the “ Exchange Act” ) and Securities and Exchange Rule 10b-5 promulgated thereunder. Plaintiff brought this action as a class action pursuant to Rules 23 (a) and (b)(3) F.R.C.P. Defendants filed a Motion to Dismiss. The Motion to Dismiss alleged that the Complaint is fatally defective for failure to allege individual reliance upon misrepresenta tions of Defendants. Discovery and class certification were deferred pur suant to agreed orders pending a ruling by the District Court on Defendants’ Motion to Dismiss. On August 20, 1986, the District Court dismissed the Plaintiff’s Complaint without prejudice based upon an in terpretation of Shores vs. Sklar, 647 F.2d 462 (5th Cir. 1981) (en banc), cert, denied, 459 TT.S. 1102 (1983), to the 3 effect that a plaintiff in the Fifth Circuit who purchases securities in an established market cannot rely upon the integrity of the market pursuant to the fraud on the market doctrine, but must plead and prove individual reliance upon specific misrepresentations. On May 27, 1986, the Fifth Circuit reversed and re manded, holding that to the extent that Plaintiff’s Com plaint alleged a scheme to defraud or course of business operating as a fraud, Plaintiff had properly pled causes of action under 10b-5(l) and (3). Plaintiff did not have to plead specific reliance upon alleged misrepresentations. The Fifth Circuit affirmed the District Court’s dismissal of Plaintiff’s Complaint with respect to claims under 10b- 5(2), holding that under Shores, any fraud on the market claim under section (2) is barred by Plaintiff’s failure to allege that she read and relied on any of the documents now claimed to have misrepresented the financial condi tion of Docutel. On August 29, 1987, the District Court stayed this action pending this Court’s ruling on Petitioner’s petition for a writ of certiorari. --------------- o--------------- . STATEMENT OF FACTS Defendant Docutel/Olivetti Corporation (“ Docutel” ) is a Delaware corporation with executive offices in Irving, Texas. On October 1, 1983, Docutel had issued and out standing 6,800,000 shares of common stock owned by more than 3,200 shareholders. Docutel’s shares were traded in 4 the over-the-counter market. Defendant Ing. C. Olivetti and C., S.p.A. (“ Olivetti” ) is an Italian corporation with its executive offices located in Italy. Olivetti acquired practical control of Docutel by means of a merger between a subsidiary of Olivetti and Docutel, and the issuance of a warrant by Docutel to the Olivetti subsidiary. Defen dants B. J. Meredith and Emmett R. DeMoss were, re spectively, the chief executive officer and executive vice president and chief financial officer of Docutel. Defendants Carlo DeBenedetti and Simone Fubini were respectively the chief executive officer and chief operating officer of Olivetti. Defendant Elserino M. Piol was a representative of Olivetti who acted as a director of Docutel. On December 5, 1983, Plaintiff purchased 300 shares of Docutel on the public market at $14-5/8 per share, for a total price of $4,474.75. Plaintiff alleged that the quarterly earnings of Docutel reported through 1983 were substantially overstated, and losses were understated, by reason of the failure of Docu tel, and Olivetti as its controlling shareholder, and the re spective officers, to charge off worthless inventories ac quired from Olivetti and its subsidiary. Docutel was made to buy inventory from Olivetti which was unsalable, giving- rise to the write-downs complained of by Plaintiff in this action. Plaintiff relied upon the integrity of the public market for Docutel shares in making her purchases and thereby incurred losses by paying the artificially inflated public market prices resulting from the fraudulently overstated earnings. 5 Oil February 16, 1984, Docutel announced a projected net loss for tbe year ended December 31, 1983, in the amount of $14,000,000. On April 2, 1984, the Wall Street Journal reported that Docutel said its previously projected net loss for 1983 of $14,000,000 would be significantly wider. In its 10-K for 1983 Docutel reported an after tax loss of $18,263,000 for 1983. The loss included $10,900,000 of inventory write-downs, approximately $10,100,000 of which was recorded in the fourth quarter. Significantly, Docutel made the following admission in its 1983 Form 10-K: In 1983, the Company’s record keeping procedures and accounting staff were strained due to the significant growth in transaction volume resulting from the merger with Olivetti Corporation, attrition of per sonnel, and the transfer in the second half of 1983 of OPD accounting function from Tarrytown, New York, to the Company’s headquarters in Irving, Texas. Docutel’s stock plummeted from a high of $38-7/8 in 1983 to a closing bid price on April 6, 1984 of $7-1/4, caus ing public investors to take large losses. --------------- o---------------- REASONS FOR DENYING THE PETITION I. RESPONDENTS WERE ENTITLED TO A REBUT TABLE PRESUMPTION OF RELIANCE UNDER THE FRAUD ON THE MARKET THEORY The Fifth Circuit Court of Appeals in this case cor rectly held that since Respondent had alleged a scheme to defraud or course of business operating as a fraud in viola 6 tion of Rule 10b-5(l) and (3), Respondent was entitled to a rebuttable presumption of reliance upon proof of material ity of the alleged conduct. Reliance is generally a requirement to a claim stated under Rule 10b-5. Proof of reliance establishes that the damaged party was induced to act by the defendant’s con duct ; it defines the causal link between defendant’s miscon duct and the plaintiff’s decision to buy or sell securities. Dupuy v. Dupuy, 551 F.2d 1005, at 1016 (5th Cir. 1977), cert, denied, 434 U.S. 911 (1977); FinJcel v. Docutel/Oli- vetti, 817 F.2d 356 at 359 (5th Cir. 1987). The fraud on the market doctrine, adopted by every Circuit Court of Appeals to consider it1 permits a plaintiff to rely upon the integrity of an established market to set a price untainted by fraud, without pleading individual reli ance upon specific misrepresentations. Most courts have held that a plaintiff is entitled only to a presumption of re liance, which may be rebutted by defendants. In this case, the Court of Appeals held that Defendants may rebut the presumption of reliance in two ways: 1) by showing that the nondisclosures did not affect the market price for the ^ e e Pei I v. Speiser, 806 F.2d 1154 (3d Cir. 1986); Levinson v. Basic, 786 F.2d 741 (6th Cir. 1986), cert, granted, 107 S. Ct. 1284 (Feb. 23, 1987); Harris v. Union Electric Co., 787 F.2d 355 (8th Cir. 1986), cert, denied, No. 85-2036 (Oct. 6, 1986); Upton v. Documentation, Inc., 734 F.2d 740 (11th Cir. 1984), cert, de nied, 469 U.S. 1132 (1985); T.J. Raney & Sons, Inc. v. Fort Cobb, Oklahoma Irrigation Fuel Authority, 717 F.2d 1330 (10th Cir. 1983), cert, denied, 465 U.S. 1026 (1984); Shores v. Sklar, 647 F,2d 462 (5th Cir. 1981), cert, denied, 459 U.S. 1102 (1983); Panzirer v. W o lf, 663 F.2d 365 (2d Cir. 1981), vacated as moot after cert, granted, 459 U.S. 1027 (1982); Ross v. A.H. Robins Co., 607 F.2d 545, 553 (2d Cir. 1979), cert, denied, 446 U.S. 946 (1980); Blackie v. Barrack, 524 F.2d 891 (9th Cir. 1975), cert. denied, 429 U.S. 816 (1976). security; or 2) that plaintiff would have purchased the stock at the same price even if she had known the informa tion that was not disclosed. Docutel, 817 F.2d at 364-365. The fraud on the market doctrine is premised upon the theory that the market price for a security, in an open and developed market, accurately reflects the value of that se curity if all relevant information has been disclosed in the marketplace.2 When one fails to disclose or misrepresents material information about a security, the market’s effic ient pricing mechanism is skewed and the price of the secur ity is distorted. Docutel, 817 F.2d at 360. The fraud on the market doctrine recognizes the fact that most investors do not carefully examine all available information about a security because there is too much, and much of it is too technical.3 Instead the typical investor relies upon the in- 7- 2This is a conclusion of the efficient market theory. The theory states that the market price reflects all representations concerning the stock. The market price of securities is a func tion of the information the market possesses, both positive and negative, assuming all information is disclosed. In re LTV Se curities Litigation, 88 F.R.D. 134, 144 (N.D.Texas 1980). See LTV for citations to the economic theories and leading works which support the doctrine. See also, Fischel, Use of Modern Finance Theory in Securities Fraud Cases Involving Actively Traded Se curities, 38 Bus.L 1 (1982); Fama, Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical W ork, 25 j.Fin. 383 (1970); Note, Fraud-on-the-Market Theory, 95 Harv.L.Rev. 1143 (1982); Note, The Efficient Capital Market Hypothesis, Economic Theory and the Regulation of the Securities Industry, 29 Stan. L. Rev. 1031 (1977). 35ee, Fischel, 38 Bus. Law, 1, 2 -5 ; Docutel, 817 F.2d at 360 n. 9 ("[R jecent scholarship suggests that the dissenters' vision of individual investors reading and relying upon information re quired to be disclosed in registration statements and the like is suspect. Most SEC disclosure documents not only go unread by their intended recipients but in fact 'can only be used effectively by market professionals.'") (quoting Note, The Fraud-on-the- Market Theory, 95 Harv.L.Rev. 1143, 1159 (1982) and H. Kripke, The SEC and Corporate Disclosure at 14 (1979)). 8 tegrity of the market to be free from deception and to value accurately a security in light of all the material information about the security. The market becomes the theoretical agent of the investor. Consequently, a purchaser or seller who relies on the market to value the security accurately suffers damages if the market does not have all the infor mation or if some of the information is false. The ability of an investor to rely upon the market price for securities as reflecting an individual issuer’s prospects is critical to liquidity in the nation’s capital markets. Most investors rely upon the integrity of the public market when they invest. The typical investor has insufficient time to review all of the data available with respect to individual securities considered for purchase. Thus, there are im portant economic bases, as well as legal bases, for the fraud on the market doctrine. It is for these reasons that the fraud on the market doctrine has been adopted in every cir cuit to consider it. See note 1 above. II. THE FRAUD ON THE MARKET DOCTRINE FUR THERS THE CLEAR INTENT OF CONGRESS. Petitioners wrongly contend that in adopting Section 10(b) of the Securities and Exchange Act of 1934, 15 U.S.C. §78j(b), Congress intended to incorporate the basic ele ments of common law fraud. Petitioners mischaracterize Congress’ intent in an attempt to overturn the fraud on the market doctrine against the great weight of judicial, scho lastic and administrative authority that supports it.4 The 4See supra note 1 and accompanying text; Docutel, 817 F.2d at 361 (“ The Securities and Exchange Commission accepts the efficient market hypothesis, which underlies the fraud on the (Continued on next page) 9 creation of the many new rules contained in the ’33 and ’34 Acts constitutes Congressional recognition of the inability of state common law principles to deal with securities fraud. Nowhere in the text of Section 10(b), or Rule 10b-5 promulgated thereunder, are the alleged elements of com mon law fraud required.5 Section 10(b) was deliberately couched in broad terms and intended to be a catch-all to prevent manipulative devices that theretofore ran ram pant.6 (Continued from previous page) market theory.") (footnote omitted); see also Black, Fraud on the Market: A Criticism of Dispensing w ith Reliance Require ments in Certain Open Market Transactions, 62 N.C.L.Rev. 435 (1984); Rapp, Rule 10b-5 and "Fraud-on-the-Market"— Heavy Seas Meet Tranquil Shores, 39 Wash.& Lee L.Rev. 861 (1982); Note, Fraud on the Market: An Emerging Theory of Recovery Under SEC Rule 10b-5, 50 Geo. Wash. L. Rev. 627 (1982); Note, Fraud-on-the-Market Theory, 95 Harv. L. Rev. 1143 (1982). 5At the outset, Petitioners cite Kardon v. National Gypsum, 69 F.Supp. 512 (E.D.Penn. 1946) for the proposition that the cause of action under Rule 10b-5 has always incorporated the basic elements of the common law deceit action. This is simply not correct. In National Gypsum the plaintiffs made claims based upon both common law fraud and Rule 10b-5. The court held that plaintiff's allegations sustained both claims. Nowhere did the court require the allegations of a common law fraud claim as a prerequisite to a claim under Rule 10b~5. The court simply held that the allegations as they were made sufficed to uphold claims under both 10b-5 and common law fraud. 6ln summing up Section 9(c) before the House Committee, which without significant alteration became Section 10(b) of the Act, one of the principal drafters said the following: "Subsection (c) says, 'Thou shalt not devise any other cun ning devices.' . . . O f course subsection . . . (c) is a catch all clause to prevent manipulative devices!.] I do not think there is any objection to that kind of a clause. The Commission should have authority to deal with new manip ulative devices." (Continued on next page) 10 The fraud on the market theory actually embraces Congress’ intent. The fraud on the market theory adheres to legislative intent by fostering public confidence in the markets, by deterring fraud and by promoting judical ef ficiency through the class action vehicle. Restoring investor confidence in the securities mar kets was a primary reason for adopting the federal securi ties laws. See 1 A. Bromberg & L. Lowenfels, Securities Fraud and Commodities Fraud, Section 2.2(110) at 2:13 (1986) (“ [Statutory antifraud provisions] were part of the initial New Deal response to the financial debacle of the 1920’s, investigations of which revealed widespread fraud, manipulation and victimization of public investors by con cealment of relevant information” ). With respect to Sec tion 10 and Rule 10b-5, courts have held that “ [t]he statute and rule are designed to foster an expectation that securities markets are free from fraud—an expectation on which purchasers should be able to rely.” Blackie v. Bar rack, 524 F.2d at 907; see also, Lipton v. Documation, 734 F.2d at 748. The ability of an investor to rely upon the honesty and integrity of the market is critical to liquidi ty in the nation’s capital markets. As one court has noted, “ it is hard to imagine that there ever is a buyer or seller who does not rely on market integrity. Who would know continued from previous page) Testimony of Thomas G. Corcoran, Hearing on HR 7852 and HR 8720 before the House Committee on Interstate and Foreign Commerce, 73d Congress, 2d Sess., 115 (1934). The courts have quoted this comment in giving broad interpretation to Section 10(b). See, e.g., Blue Chip Stamps v. Manor Drug Stores, 421 U.S. 723, 766 (1975) (dissent of Blackmun J.); SEC v. Texas Gulf Sulphur Co., 401 F.2d 833, 859 (2d Cir. 1968) (en banc), cert, denied, 394 U.S. 976 (1969). 11 ingly roll the dice in a crooked crap game?” Schlanger v. Four-Phase Systems, Inc., 555 F.Supp. 535, 538 (S.D. N.Y. 1982). The fraud on the market doctrine recognizes the fact that the legislative policy designed to foster investor ex pectations of honesty in the securities markets has become reality. Investors rely upon the integrity of the market when they invest. They purchase upon the assumption that the market price is free from any unsuspected manipula tion that could inflate the market price. The fraud on the market doctrine simply furthers the goals of the securities laws by protecting those that rely on the integrity of the market when they invest. Blackie v. Barrack, 524 F.2d at 907. Such investors may recover from corporate wrong doers without proving individual reliance on specific mis representations, but by showing that they relied upon the integrity of the market when they purchased the security —an expectation on which purchasers should be able to rely. Requiring direct proof from each purchaser that he relied on a particular representation when purchasing would defeat recovery by those whose reliance was indirect or on the integrity of the public market place. The securi ties laws would operate to protect only those investors with enough time and sophistication to digest all informa tion disseminated into the public market, despite the fact that all investors who rely on the honesty of the market suffer the damage of purchasing a security at a price in flated by material misrepresentations. To leave such open market purchasers unprotected is not consistent with the policies under the federal securities laws. Investors should and do rely upon the integrity of the public market when they invest. 12 To the extent that private securities fraud actions may be prosecuted more efficiently by adoption of the fraud on the market theory, the enforcement of the securities laws, and the underlying goal of honest markets, are fur thered. Brief for the Securities and Exchange Commission as Amicus Curiae at 26, Basic v. Levinson, No. 86-279 (U.S. filed April 1987). There is no doubt that implied pri vate actions under 10b-5 effectively enforce the securities laws. Id. (The Securities and Exchange Commission noted that the Supreme Court has “ repeatedly . . . emphasized . . . that implied private actions [under Rule 10b-5] pro vide ‘ a most effective weapon in the enforcement’ of the securities laws and are ‘ a necessary supplement to Com mission action.’ ” (quoting Bateman Eichler, Rill Rich ards, Inc. v. Berner, 472 U.S. 299, 310 (1985)). Federal securities laws were also adopted for the pur pose of efficiency in enforcing in one case all claims that arise out of a single transaction. As commentators have written, The securities laws create nationwide service of pro cess and have a liberal venue rule that permits litiga tion to consolidate all defendants and all claims in a single forum. The class action device created by Rule 23 of the Rules of Civil Procedure makes it easy to bring all plaintiffs together. Easterbrook and Fisehel, Mandatory Disclosure and the Protection of Investors, 70 Ya.L.Rev. 669, at 680 (1984). The fraud on the market doctrine has special and obvious appeal in class actions because the need to prove a per sonalized reliance by each class member is avoided. The question of reliance usually arises in the context of whether 13 or not to certify a class.7 If a plaintiff in a securities fraud action must plead and prove individual reliance, then class certification is probably improper, because issues of individual reliance will predominate. If the class action procedural device can no longer be used to handle major securities cases, then defendants will gain some measure of relief because not all defrauded investors will sue. As one commentator pointed out: The only person whose behavior is likely to be changed are would-be defrauders, because the fraud-on-the- market theory, by eliminating issues of individual re liance, facilitates class action recovery of claims that would otherwise be too small to be litigated individual ly. And here, possibly, lies an unstated rationale for the fraud-on-the-market decisions, almost all of which involved class actions: only if courts allow class ac tions to proceed will under-inclusive recoveries and hence a failure to deter fraud at its inception be avoided. (footnote omitted) Note, Fraud-on-the-Market Theory, 95 Harv.L.Rev. 1143, at 1159 (1982). Moreover, there will no doubt be many separate suits filed by investors who are in a position to plead and prove individual reliance. The cost to the judicial system in litigating each of such suits separately will likely be unacceptable. Petitioners argue that the fraud on the market doctrine is inconsistent with the full disclosure policy of the se 7For example, in In re LTV Securities Litigation, 88 F.R.D. 134 (N.D.Tex. 1980), the question of whether to apply the fraud on the market doctrine arose in the context of a motion to cer tify a class of more than 100,000 members who traded nine (9) different types of securities over a period of three and a half years. Id. at 140. 14 curities laws. Such is not correct. In fact, it is obvious that the fraud on the market doctrine could not exist with out the full disclosure contemplated by the securities laws. The doctrine assumes that the markets have assimilated all available information. However, liquidity in the mar kets requires that investors who have not had an opportuni ty to read every disclosure made by a company, or who may not be sophisticated enough to understand all the dis closures, may nevertheless invest at the market price upon the assumption that such price represents the consensus price established by interested and informed investors. “ Various market professionals still have an incentive to secure information until a marginal dollar invested in pro cessing information equals the profits to be made from trading on superior forecasting.” 8 Petitioners’ argument that the fraud, on the market doctrine establishes a policy of “ investor’s insurance” im plies that each investor can collect his full damages in the event he loses money as a result of securities fraud. This contention is totally unfounded. Even if individual re liance is presumed until defendants have an opportunity to rebut the presumption, it remains necessary for de frauded investors to prove fraud. What Petitioners seek 8Fischel, Use of Modern Finance Theory in Securities Fraud Cases Involving Actively Traded Securities, 38 Bus.L. 1, at 4 (1982). Professor Fischel explains it, "Markets may be analyzed as having two classes of participants. One class will have a comparative advantage, actors in this class have an incentive to invest in gathering and analyzing information and to take actions to affect the market. The other class, however, lacking a comparative advantage, has no incentive to invest in process ing information because it cannot profit thereby. The first group will earn a superior return commensurate with their greater in vestment skill." Id. 15 is practical immunity from prosecution for corporate wrongdoers. Even if a defrauded investor can prove lia bility, the plaintiff still recovers only his out-of-pocket dam ages. The out-of-pocket damage rule established in Green v. Occidental, 541 F.2d 1335, 1341 (9th Cir. 1976) (Sneed, J., concurring); see, e.g., In re LT V Securities Litigation, 88 F.RJD. 134 (NJD.Tex. 1980), permits an investor to re cover only that portion of his total loss which is due to defendants’ fraud. While most class actions are indeed settled, the settlements frequently result in a recovery of only pennies on the dollar to defrauded investors. This is scarcely a plan for “ investor insurance,” but is an ef fective plan for keeping corporate management as honest as possible. Petitioners’ argument that upholding fraud on the market claims under Rule 10b-5 constitutes the effective repeal of Section 18(a) is similarly unfounded. Petition ers ignore the fact that in this case Plaintiff alleges a scheme to defraud the market by disseminating fraudulent information not only in the SEC filings, but also in pub licly disseminated reports appearing in The Wall Street Journal. Section 18(a) limits its remedy to fraudulent SEC filings. Furthermore, this Court has already re jected an interpretation of the securities laws that dis places an action under Section 10(b) merely because of the availability of express remedies under other sections. In Herman d MacLean v. Huddleston, 459 U.S. 375, 384- 387 (1983) this court said, “ In savings clauses included in the 1933 and 1934 Acts, Congress rejected the notion that the express remedies of the securities laws would preempt all other rights of action . . . We therefore reject an interpretation of the securities laws that displaces an 16 action under Section 10(b).” (footnotes omitted). A cu mulative construction of the securities laws furthers the broad remedial purposes of the securities laws and fur thers Congress’ intent in enacting the 1934 Act, “ to im pose requirements necessary to make [securities] regula tion and control reasonably complete and effective.” Id. (quoting 15 USC Section 78b [15 USCS Section 78b]). Courts have similarly rejected the notion that there must be additional and differing elements contained in a Section 10(b) claim to justify a civil remedy under 10(b) when other remedies were available under other sections of the Securities Acts. See, e.g., Chemetron Corp. v. Bus iness Funds, Inc., 718 F.2d 725 (5th Cir. 1983). None theless, plaintiffs face a more difficult task in stating a claim under section 10(b) where plaintiff must allege scienter, as opposed to stating a claim under Section 18 where an allegation of scienter is not a requirement. Ross v. A.II.Robins Co., 607 F.2d 545, 556 (2d Cir. 1979), cert, denied, 446 U.S. 949 (1980). III. THIS COURT HAS PREVIOUSLY CONSIDERED THE INDIVIDUAL RELIANCE ISSUE IN THE SECURITIES FRAUD CONTEXT Two decisions by this Court, Mills v. Electric Auto- Lite Co., 396 U.S. 375 (1970) and Affiliated TJte Citizens v. United Slates, 406 U.S. 128 (1972), demonstrate this Court’s recognition that under certain circumstances, causation in a securities fraud suit is adequately estab lished by proof of materiality, without direct proof of in dividual reliance. In Mills this court expressly noted the judicial utility in substituting materiality for direct proof of reliance in 17 large securities fraud cases. In Mills, minority share holders alleged, under Section 14(a) of the Exchange Act, 15 U.S.C. Section 78n(a) (1976), that shareholder approval of a merger had been obtained via a misleading proxy statement. This Court acknowledged that “ reliance by thousands of individuals . . . can scarcely be inquired into.'’ Id. at 380 (citation omitted). As an alternative, this Court stated, There is no need to supplement this [materiality] re quirement . . . with a requirement of proof of wheth er the defect actually had a decisive effect on the vot ing. Where there has been a finding of materiality, a shareholder has made a sufficient showing of causal relationship between the violation and the injury . . . Id. at 384-85. The Mills case is also informative because this Court found liability without proof of individual re liance, even though Mills involved an implied remedy un der Section 14(a). Like Section 10(b) of the Exchange Act, the remedy under Section 14(a) is a judicially implied remedy. In Affiliated Ute, a Rule lQb-5 case, this Court dis pensed with the need of plaintiffs to establish reliance in nondisclosure cases involving open market transactions. Like the Court of Appeals in this case, this Court noted the distinction between paragraph (2) of rule 10b-5 and paragraphs (1) and (3), saying that the former is re stricted to “ the making of an untrue statement of a ma terial fact and the omission to state a material fact.” Id. at 152-153. Nevertheless, this Court continued, the first and third paragraphs are not so restricted, they deal with a course of business or a device, scheme, or artifice that operated as a fraud. Id. Thus, this Court held, 1 8 Under the . circumstances of this case, involving pri marily a failure to disclose, positive proof of reliance is not a prerequisite to recovery. All that is necessary is that the facts withheld he material in the sense that a reasonable investor might have considered them im portant in the making of this decision . . . . This ob ligation to disclose and this withholding of a material fact establish the requisite element of causation in fact. Id. 153-154. Affiliated Ute has been widely interpreted as eliminating plaintiff’s need to establish reliance in non disclosure cases involving open market transactions. E.g., Vervaecke v. Chiles, Heider & Co., 578 F.2d 713, 717 (8th Cir. 1978); Rifkin v. Crow, 574 F.2d 262-63; Dorfman v. First Boston Corp., 62 F.R.D. 466, 471 (E.D.Pa. 1974). The decision by the Court of Appeals below hardly conflicts with decisions by this Court. To the contrary, the decision below embraces policies long recognized by this Court that in certain securities fraud suits, material ity oftentimes sufficiently establishes causation in fact. Where through a scheme to defraud or course of business a defendant disseminates misrepresentations that artifici ally inflate the market price for a security, plaintiffs should be entitled to a presumption of reliance upon prov ing materiality. IV. PETITIONERS DO NOT HAVE STANDING TO ASSERT THE CONFLICT WITHIN THE CIR CUITS AS A REASON FOR THIS COURT TO GRANT CERTIORARI. Article III of the constitution limits the judicial power of the United States to resolution Of “ cases” and “ contro versies.” As an incident to this requirement, this Court 19 has always required that a litigant have “ standing.” To have “ standing” a litigant must show that he personally has some actual or threatened injury. Valley Forge Col lege v. Americans United, 454 U.S. 464, 471-473, 70 L.Ed. 2d 700, 102 S.Ct. 752 (1982). On page fifteen of their brief, Petitioners urge this Court to grant certiorari because of an alleged conflict within the Circuits. Petitioners contend that the Fifth Circuit’s decision in this case is in conflict with decisions in other Circuits. In this case the Fifth Circuit held that a plaintiff is permitted to assert a fraud on the market theory under 10b-5(l) and (3), but not under 10b-5(2). In 10b-5(2) cases, plaintiffs must still prove individual reliance upon specific misrepresentations. In their opin ion, the Fifth Circuit recognized that other Circuits permit the fraud on the market theory under 10b-5(2).9 Never theless, the Court declined to so hold and for this reason upheld the District Court’s dismissal of Respondent’s claim stated under 10b-5(2). The Fifth Circuit’s decision thus favored Petitioners. Due to the conflict, Petitioners need only defend themselves against claims stated under 10b-5(l) and (3). Consequently, Petitioners cannot urge the conflict among Circuits as a basis for this Court to grant certiorari. Petitioners have suffered no injury. They have actually benefited from the conflict among Cir cuits. It is Respondent who has suffered injury by virtue of the conflict among Circuit Courts. If Respondent could 9See, e.g., Peil v. Speiser, 806 F.2d 1162-63; Upton v. Docu- mation, 734 F.2d 740; Blackie v. Barrack, 524 F.2d 891. 20 have brought this action in the Third or Eleventh Circuits, her claim under 10b-5(2) would not have been dismissed. Such is not the case, however, and Respondent has suf fered an injury in the dismissal of part of her case. Not withstanding the conflict among Circuit Courts, the injury is peculiar to Respondent, and Respondent alone may urge the conflict among the Circuits. V. THIS CASE DIFFERS FROM BASIC V. LEVIN SON WHICH IS CURRENTLY BEFORE THIS COURT. On page 19 of their brief Petitioners argue that this Court should consider this case as a companion to Levin son v. Basic, 786 F.2d 741 (6th Cir. 1986), cert, granted, 107 S.Ct. 1284 (Feb. 23, 1987) (No. 86-279). These cases differ, however, and should not be considered as com panion cases. First, as admitted by Petitioners, Basic, Inc. raises the issue in the context of class certification under Fed.R.Civ.P. 23(b)(3). The standard of review is abuse of discretion. In this case, the issues arise under a Fed.R.Civ.P. 12(b)(6) motion to dismiss, presenting a pure question of law. Thus, these cases are to be re viewed under differing standards. Second, Basic, Inc. does not distinguish between causes of action stated under 10b-5(l) and (3), and causes of action stated under 10b-5(2). Basic, Inc. considers ma terial misrepresentations in public statements relating to the existence of merger negotiations. There is no issue as to a scheme to defraud or course of business that operated as a fraud. Basic, Inc. is primarily a 10b-5(2) case. This case on the other hand hinges on a scheme to defraud or 21 course of business to defraud in violation of Rule 10b-5(l) and (3). Further, Basic, Inc. presents questions of whether sellers may utilize the fraud on the market doctrine as well as purchasers. This issue is not presented on this appeal. --------------- o------------— — 22 CONCLUSION For the foregoing reasons, the Petition For A Writ Of Certiorari to review the decision of the United States Court of Appeals for the Fifth Circuit should he denied. Respectfully submitted, R oger F. Claxton Bar Card No. 04329000 2900 First RepublicBank Plaza 901 Main Street, LB-180 Dallas, Texas 75202 (214) 741-6781 Attorney for Respondent W. D. M asterson T heodore C. A nderson K ilgore & K ilgore 2900 First RepublicBank Plaza 901 Main Street, LB-180 Dallas, Texas 75202 (214) 741-6781 J ules B rody S t u l l , S tu ll & B rody 6 East 45th Street New York, New York 10017 (212) 687-7230 OF COUNSEL September 1987.