An Outline for Racial Bloc Voting Analysis Paper
Working File
June 8, 1983

Cite this item
-
Case Files, Thornburg v. Gingles Working Files - Guinier. An Outline for Racial Bloc Voting Analysis Paper, 1983. e1ef9898-e192-ee11-be37-6045bdeb8873. LDF Archives, Thurgood Marshall Institute. https://ldfrecollection.org/archives/archives-search/archives-item/264f0f0c-3e62-481a-9d9c-85f33903aa1c/an-outline-for-racial-bloc-voting-analysis-paper. Accessed May 22, 2025.
Copied!
School of Social Sciences [Jniversity of California, Irvine AN OUTLINE FOR RACIAL BLOC VOTING ANALYSIS* Bernard Grofman Professor of Polltical Sclence N'lcholas Novlel lo Doctoral Candldate School of Soclal Sclences Unlversity of Callfornla, Irvlne Irvlne, Callfornla 92717 June I, .I983 Sectlon IX of thls paper 'ls not f or quotatlon 1n 1 ts present form *Acknow1edgments: Thls research was part'la11y supported by NSF Grant #SES 8l-07554, Program 1n Po'lltlcal Sclence. I'le are lndebted to Kathy Albertl, Llll'lan !,lh1te, Helen !{1ldman, cheryl Larsson, Dee yox, and 0avld l{esthof f of the llord Processlng Center of the School of Soc'lal Sclences, Unlverslty of Ca1'lforn1a, Irvlne, for typlng a large number of rough drafts of thls manuscrlpt. l{e would also llke to acknowledge the helpful dlscusslons of related lssues the senlor author has had wlth Charles Cotrell, Robert Br'lschetto, Fred Cervantes, and Jose Garza. After theflrst draft of thls artlcle was completed we became aware of the work of James Loewen (.l982) and earl'ler references whlch he cltes and whlch we have now l ncorporated and bu'l I t upon. Al1 J udgments expressed 1n th'ls artlcle are, however, the so'le responslbll'lty of the authors. An earller verslon of thts paper was presented at a pane'l on "Soclal Sclence 1n the Courtroom" at the Southwestern Soclal Sc'lences Heetlng, Houston, Texas, Harch 17-20, .l983 it. TABLE OF CONTENTS I. Introduction. III. Bas'ic Model for Single Member District Two Candidate General Elect jons Involving a Bl ack Candidate and a l,Jh jte Candidate Where Registration (or Population) Data by Race are Available for Each Voting District. Measuring the Extent of Racial BIoc Voting irt Sing'le Member D'i stricts 0ther Regression Approaches. 20 l3 17 35 6l 23 ?) 42 50 52 IV. Mod'ification to the Basic Model for the Single Member District General Election Case Where There is More than One Candidate of a Given Race V. Modification to the Basic Model for the Single Member District Case for Primary rather than General El ecti ons Vi. Extending the Bas'ic Model for the Single Member District General Election Case to Allow for Differential Turnout and Voter Choice by Race and by Party . VI I . Coping with the Unavai l abi f ity (or Populatjon) Data by Race. Vi I I. Modification D'i stricts or Place System. of Regi stration to the Analysi s for the Case At-1arge Elections Without a of Mul timember Desi gnated IX. Estimating the Possible Type Proportion of Ballot Patterns of Each Cast by Bl ack/hlh'ite Democrat/Non-Democrati c Al low'ing For Different'ial Choice by Race Voters. Tables. Vari abl e Li st Appendix A: Appendix B: and by Party. 64 I. introduction The problem with which this paper will deal is the measurement of racial (or Iinguistic or ethnic) polarization'in voting at both the primary and general election level jn both single-member djstrict elections (or at-large elections with numbered places) and multimember district elect'ions. Proving the existence of bloc voting along racial or linguist'ic lines is often an'important component of cases a1'leging vote dilution of. a racial or linguistic minority. (See e.9., McMillan v. Escambia County of Florida, 688 F. 2d 960 at 966 n. .l2.) The techniques we offer are intended to provide a standardized methodology through wh'ich measures of the extent of racial or linguist'ic bloc voting can be obtained, and include all the methods commonly used as well as a number of modifications and extensions (€.9., to the case of multimember d'istrjct electjons without a numbered place system) that we have 'l developed.' We shall provide techniques of analysis both for the case where data on the racia'l compos'ition of the electorate or potential electorate in each voting prec'inct'is available and for the case where the only d'irectly racially relevant data that are available are the vote shares of the Black (tihite) cand'idate(s) in each voting precinct. lFor simplicity, we shall henceforth discuss only Black minorit'ies, but the results we offer are, of course, appl'icable to any identifiable group. Again for simplicity we present our models'in terms of Black candidate(s) vs. White candidate(s) contests, but the same kind of analysis would apply if we were dealing with candidates who were the same race but whose electoral support varied with the race of the voters. 2 II. Basic Model for Single-Member Djstrict Two-Candidate General Elections Involving a Black Candidate and a White Cand'idate Where Registration (or Populat'ion) Data by Race Are Ava'ilable for Each Voting'Precinct For simp'l'icity, I et us assume that regi strat'ion data by race by voting precinct are ava'ilable. The analysis for the case where the available data are on the racial compos'it'ion of the populat'ion in each voting prec'inct (rather than on the racial composition of the registered voters) is essentially identical to that we give below. Let2 = the proportion of total registration which is lih i te I -x = the proport'ion of total regi strati on whi ch 'i s Black PWW = the proportion of White registered voters who vote for the White candidate Pgw = the proportion of Black registered voters who vote for the !,lhite candidate Pgg = the proportion of Black registered voters who vote for the Black candidate PWa = the proportion of White registered voters who vote for the Black candidate 2R t ist of all variables used 'in th'is paper along w'ith their def i n'itions i s prov'ided at the back to assi st the reader. 3 Pw = f,he proportion of total reg'istered voters who vote for the White candidate PB = lhe proport'ion of tota'l regi stered voter s who vote for the Black candidate f = the proportion of registered voters who vote Tw = Pl,lw * P,,B = the proportion of registered white voters who vote TB = PBB * PB,u = the proportion of registered Black voters who vote (N0TEt PtllB + P*, S 1, PBB * PBw 5 I' and Pw * PB I l, since some white (Black) registered vote s may not vote. ) It is true by defjn'ition that, for the electorate as a whole, we must hav e Py1 = X(fuur) + (l - x) (Psy); i.e., P,,=(Pww-Pr*)x*PB,,, Let P!{(j) = the value of Pw in the ith voting precinct, etc.; j.€., in general, we shall use the superscript (i) to denote the value of a variable in the'ith voting precinct. Hence if t,l') = *rX11) + bt for al1 i, then P,..,u = *l * bl PBtl = bl ; i.e., if we regress P,, on x, then the slope and intercept have a straiqhtf orward "natura1" 'interpretation, 'in terms of the propo tion of l^/hite (Bl ack ) reqi stered voters who vote f or the lrJhite candidate. ) S'imi I arly, i f we regrest PB on x, we obtai n' PUJB = nZ+ bZ PBB = bz Analogously, if we regress P,, on l-x, then we obta'in PWW as the intercept of that regression equation; wh'ile if we regress PA I - x, we obtajn' PWg as the'intercept of that regression equation Let us specify a new notation such that D Dr = '|,Jl,,J 'wl^l Pww * PwB 0n Dl =.BI,J etc. Bl^l %.g*r&; 3hle have deliberately chosen to do those regressions in terms of proportions rather than raw numbers. Virtually identical equations can be defined for the case where we look at the number of Black (l,lhite) reg'istrants, and at the number of voters tor ffiE-Wh jte (Bl ack ) cand'idate inltead of at proportion{-6G the parameters (especial'ly the intercept) do not have as direct and immed'iately meaningful interpretations as 'in the regression equations based on proportjons defined above, since using raw numbers confounds d'ifferences caused by differjng propens'ities of White and Black voters to vote for Black candidates with effects caused by differential voter turnout among White and Black voters, since tota'l vote for Black candidates wjll be lowered in precjncts wjth high Black population if Black turnout is lower than Wh'ite turnout. This effect wi11, in general, lead to an underestimation of the maglitude of -Py1y1jf raw numbers rather than proportions are used. The differential turnout issue ure consider separately below. The methodology we use is based on that'in Goodman (.1953), a classic art'icle whose techniques have become part of the standard statistical tool kit (see e.g., Loewen, .l982; Langbein and Lichtman, .l978). 5 These primed variables give us the White (Black) vote for Wh'ite/Black candidates as a proportjon of total White (Black) vote. It js PilW and Pig in which we shall be most interested since these denote the proportion of votes from t'Jhite (Black) voters which go to a candidate of their own race. S'imi larly we shal I let P.. D Pil=T^fu, anci Pi=tr. 0f course, Pit =l-Pi. These two primed variables give us the White (Black) share of the actual vote .4 0f course, the value of ,2 for the regress'ion equations specified on page three and four above (where r is Pearson'S correlation coefficient) tells us how good our assumption is that a constant proportion of White (81ack) registrants vote for the White (Black) cand'idate(s) and thus whether the vote share of the White (Black) candidate is 'in fact almost perfectly directly proportional to the proportion of hlh'ite (Alack) registration 'in each voting precinct, 'i .8., directly proportional to x (l - x). It is important to emphas'ize that, in analyses involving racial registration data and votes for cand'idates by the race of the candidate, r (or rZ) is not a measure of the extent of racial bloc voting. Rather, d h'igh value of r (or equivalently of rZ) is a necessary prerequis'ite for us to have 4Often those dojnq racial bloc votinq will reqress P; on x rather than P6 on f. Great care must-be taken-in inteirpreting the parameters jn such a regression equation. tie d'iscuss th'is issue'in a methodol ogical appendi x. confjdence in estimates of parameters such as PWW and Pi' which are the ones actua'l1y to be used in the measurement of the oegree of raci al polarization.5'6 Tu rnout Our est'imating procedure also tells us about (differential) turnout among White and Black registered voters, since P,.B * PWhl = T,, = proport'ion of t/hite registe ed voters who vote (i.e. White turnout as a proport'ion of White registered voters) while PBB * PBW = TB = proportion of Black registered voters who vote (i.e. Black turnout as a proport'ion of Black regi stered voters ) . We can directly estimate turnout, as a proportion of registered voters, by making use of the identity Total votesT,,* * Tr(1-x) = T = regi stered voters and regressing T on x. The intercept of this regression will give us Tg while the sum of the slope plus the'intercept will give us Tr. 5To those with statistical tra'ining, this may seem trivially obvious, but jt'is a point wh'ich federal courts have fa'iled to fu11y qrasp. (See espec'ially McMillan v. Escambia County, Florida 688 F.2d 960 it goo n. 12 ( .t 982) , one-oT-tTiFl ead 6The.e is no clear professional consensus as to what value of r is adequate. Indeed, this is a misleadjng question to ask. Art'icles appear in the major professional pof itical scjence iournals containing regressions with r values of.3 or even lower if the t-statistics for particular regression parameters 4re statist'ically significant. Values of Pearson's r above .5 are relatjvely rare in political science. Analogously if we let PD*l = proportion of registered voters who are either Democrats or Independents PR*I = proportion of reg'istered voters who are either Republicans or Independents PD = proportion of registered voters who are Democrats PR = proportion of registered voters who are Republicans, PI = proport'ion of registered voters who are Independents or unaffi'liated, TD = proport'ion of registered Democrats who vote TR*I = proportjon of registered Republjcans and Independents who vote then TDPD * TR*lPR*l = T, etc. (see Section V). Checking Realism of Parameter Estimates (l ) Verifying aggregate relationships v'ia mathematical ident'it'ies: As one check on the realism of our regress'ion-obtained estimates of P,,,,, P,,B, PBB, and Pr, (and thence of the accuracy of thejr primed equivalents), we must have certain 'identities satisfied: ,PWu,*(l-x)PBW=P,n, *PWB*(l-x)PBB=PB Analogous'ly, we must have T*x+Tr(l-x):T (2) Extreme case analysis: In order to establish further confidence in our regression-based estimates of parameters such as PilW, Pig, TA, TW 6o etc. jt is important to directly check the realism of these estimates. To do this we may look at d'istricts which are nearly all Black (t'lhite) in their voting registration. Clear'ly, in a nearly .l00 percent Black d'istrict, the share of the total vote in that precinct garnered by Black candidates'is essentially identical to ti['), while in a nearly .l00 percent White district the share of the total vote in that precinct garnered by l,lh jte candidates 'is essentially jdentjcal to ti,l'). The average values of the values of Pig and P,i* we obtain from look'ing at extreme-case (all White all Black) districts enable us to verify the reasonableness of our regreSsion-based est'imates of these Same parameters. Sim'il arly the average value of T we detain from lookjng at all White or Black districts, respect'ive1y, enables us to verify the reasonableness of our regress'ion est'imates of Tg and TW. Such a check should always be performed if a sufficient number of extreme case districts of each race are available. Be aware, however, that some differences between the regression-based estimates and those obtained from the average values of homogeneous districts (especial 1y for completely racially homogeneous districts) are to be expected. In particular, I,Jhite voters in homogeneous I^Jhite districts are very 1ike1y to be a few percentage points different in turnout and in the proport'ion of their votes which goes to Whjte candidates than is true for tJhite voters as a whole--due to both contextual effects (i.e., homogene'ity reinforcing the prevailing tendency 'in a group) and also the effects of class d'ifferences, (and perhaps also 9 part'isanship) between districts which are almost entirely l.lhite and those which contain some number of Blacks:7 (3) The method of overlapping percentages: In some cases we may not have d'istricts wh'ich are nearly 100% black or .l00% whjte but there may still exist d'istricts which are on average overwhelmingly (say 90% or more) of one race. For such districts we may make use of the methods of "overlapping-percentages" (Duncan and Davis, I953; Loewen, 1982) to determine an est'imate of the minimal bloc voting which coulci exist and stjll be compatible with the observed levels of support for the t^lhite/Bl ack candidate(s). As before let x(i) t-r(i) o (i) 'hl proportion of district proportion of district proportion of the vote the Whjte candidate(s) voters proport'ion of the vote the Black candidate(s) voters i which is White i which is Black in district i which goes to as a proportion of registered di str i ct i wh i ch goes to a proportion of registered d (i).B 1n AS TThe regress'ion-based estimates will normally be slightly superior to those obtained from extreme-case analysis, because the reg ession est'iate is based on all the data and thus provides a better estimate for the behavior of the average I,Jhite/Black voter. However, where racial polarizat'ion voting is clearcut, extreme case analysis, or the method of overlapping percentages d'iscussed below, frdJ be sufficjent to establish the presence of rac'ial bloc voting, and regression techniques superfluous. t0 . e*(i) Since even if all would still leave wh'ich has to come Simi I ar1y, 'if rf+ . *(i) , th.n P (j) - r-*(i)_ 'l^lrww5 Tjl- Bl ack voters voted f or the tlhite cand'idate(s), that a remaining vote proportion of er(i) - (l-x)(i) from White voters. *.tr(i)<t-*(i),th.n D (i) _ ,(i) ^ 'B ^PaaS t -f.rf while only (ry) 1oo percent or (4) Constra'ined percentages: The nrethod of overlappino percentages provides a conservative estjmate of the amount of racial bloc voting. In most circumstances, we bel'ieve it to be unreasonable to posit (as we did above) tnat a full .l00 percent of Black voters vote for l,,lhite cand'idates te ) e hth i (i) il ent rac at o e S a el fe ari rac her Whi te voters / that only ( \ idates, whilt of voters ol d, ceteris pt he opposite r ht fail 'if tl Bl ack cand proporti on race shoul oters of t clause mig vote for PB(i) - x candidates. It is simply unreasonable to posit 100 percent of Black voters vote for of t,Jh'ite voters do so. Clear'ly, the who vote for candidates of that same least as great as the proportion of v vote. 0f course the ceteris paribus ( 'l-x ) 1bo per a g'i ver ri bus, b ace who ere was )( rc n ll partisan contest between candjdates of djfferent races'in which each candidate was from a party opposite to the party registrat'ion held by a majority of the members of h'is/her race.) If, however, w€ I Safely assume that Pttw i Paw D rD.BB :'t,lB ' then we can improve on the method of overlapping percentages and calculate the m'in'imal poss'ible values of PgA (PWW) as follows: If ). er(i) < I - *(j), th"n Pss S PB('i ) To see th'is we need merely note that if Pgg = P,.,B then p,,J(i) = r(i,rrr,,, + 1r-x(i)1rrr(i) = pBB = p,,B Similarly, 'if l. t*(i) . x(i), *,.n Pww S P!,l(i ) If | . ,(i) . p,.(i), or L, .,-x(i) . Rr('i ) , then analogous reasoning appl ies. Regardress of whether P!{(i ) i *(t ) o. PB('i) | r-*(i I , we must have p,',(i) ,r,rtt' -illl-t , , 12 since o > (t-*(i)) (t*(') - l) , and D (i) _,(i) o (i) - 'B nrB' Tif ' since o , ,(i) (rr(,) - t) tJe shall refer to techniques such as those above as involving the method of constrained percentages. The method of overlapping percentages wil I always y'ie1d lower est'imates of the amount of rac'ial bloc voting than wiII the "constrained percentages" assumpt'ion that each race js at least as l'ike1y to vote for candidates of h'is/her own race as he/she is to vote for cand'idates of the opposite race. (5) Mixed-case analysis: Sometjmes we have extreme cases for one value of a variable but not folits other values. For example, there may be, say, some nearly all [,lhite precincts but no nearly all Black precincts. To cope with that we can use what we shall call mixed case analysis. Let q adummyvariable(inthiscase q=B or q=[,J). We h ave the i dent'i ty Pq = P!\tq (PRoP0RTIoN 0F hIHITES IN THE MIXED DISTRICTS) + Psq (PRoPoRTIoN 0F BLACKS IN THE MIXED DISTRICTS) OO 'is s'imp1y the population mean. tr' 'is obta'ined from looking at the values of tO in the all-white districts. With tO and O*O known, and the proportjon of Whites/Blacks jn the mixed districts known, we merely solve the above equation for tr'. t3 III. Measuring the Extent of Racia1 Bloc Voting in S'ing1e Member Di stricts I n I ook 'i ng at r aci al b I oc voti ng, we are concerned with what proport'ion of the voters of each race votes for cand'idates of that same race, i.e., with the extent to which voting patterns are polarized along racial lines. One way to do thjs js simply to look at PWW and Pie. If both are h'igh, then voting is clearly racially polarized. Indeed, in my view, we may have bloc vot'ing if either Pilw or Pfig are high. If our principal concern is with minority vote dilution, then the parameter of greatest interest is PilW, since that tells us the extent to which Whites are wjlling to vote for minority candidates. However, only if PU]W is high relative to PiW do we actually have a polarjzed sjtuat'ion rather than one in which both Whites and Blacks are voting predominantly for the White candidate. For single member districts it'is useful to develop a measure of racial polarization wh'ich incorporates both PWW and Pgg. We may represent raw data'in the form of a LxZ table whose entries sum to one. (See Table l.) Table I about here In a situation which is perfectly polarized for both the majority and the minority communities, the upper right-hand cell (customarily denoted b) and the bottom left-hand cell (customarily denoted c) will be zero. in this notation a is used to denote the upper left-hand cell and d For such a t4 Zx? table, a'is used to denote the lower right-hand cell. useful measure of polarjzation is Yule's Q: P D -P D'tJI^l' BB 'l.lB' Bt^l ffiBt^r n -ad-bcY ad+bc For Table 1, the expression for Yule's Q simplifies to Yule's Q = = I ndex of Rac i al Po'l ari zati on . An exactly identical value for Yule's Q would have been obta'ined had we used Figure 2'instead, where Pi,tW, Pi' etc. are used directly in a table that 'is percentaged by rows ('i .e., in which each row sum 'is one). Figure 2 about here The index of racial polarization g'iven in the equation above (Yule's Q) will normally range from 0 to l; the closer the index is to one, the greater will be the degree of overall racial polarization (b1oc voting). For single member districts, values above .6 would indicate consi derable pol ari zati on. An alternat'ive operationalization of rac'ial polarization is based on R'ice's Index of Likeness (Benson, .l969). We shal I def ine, R, the Rice Index of Racial Polarized Voting: R = 'l - R'ice Index of L'ikeness = Pt - Dl ='BB 'rlB Pilw - Priw' t5 This measure will normally run from 0 to l, but wil I usually be less than .5. For single member djstricts, values above .3 would jndicate considerable po1 ari zation.S There is no single cutoff value necessary of either R or Q to establish s'ignificant racial b'loc voting. Racial bloc voting, in our view, 'is signif icant when it leads to mjnority vote dilution, i.e ., if it 'is of sufficient magnitude that the success of minority supported cand'idates js made difficult or imposs'ible because many White voters are either unwilling to vote for Black (or Black supported) candidates, or (for mmds) are willing to vote for no more than a "token" number of m'inority canuidates. We should also emphasize that racial bloc voting must be looked at in both general electjons and primaries. The absence of rac'ial bloc voting'in a general election (especially a partisan contest) does not'imp1y the absence of rac'ial bloc voting, since such bloc voting may be present in the primary, and thus constrain the' election chances of Black cand'idates. Even the success of Black cand'idates in a given primary in no proof of the absence of racjal bloc voting, since in a multicandidate plurality election,'if l,'lhite voters divide their.votes among many candidates while Black voters do not, Black candidates can be elected even though few l.lh'ites vote for Black cand'idates; but th j s electoral success of Bl ack cand'idates may not be 8N.ith.r Q nor R voting for the nmd case appropriate measures of below. is appropriate an without a numbered rac'ial bloc voting an'index of racial bloc place system. We discuss for th'is case in Section VIIi l6 repeated in subsequent primary elections with fewer viable Whjte candidates (cf. Blacksher and Menefee, .l982: 60 and note 346; McMillan v. Escambia Cou@.ida 683 F 2d at 1241 n. 6). 17 IV. Mod'ifjcation to the Bas'ic Model for the Single-Member D'istrjct General Elect'ion Case trJhere There'is More than One Candidate of a G'iven Race To deal w'ith sing'le-member-district situat'ions where there is more than one cand'idate of a given race is not difficult. We s'imp1y redefine the proportion of votes for the l,ihite (Black) candidate as the proportion of votes for the White (B1ack) candidate. Since every voter has only one vote which can be cast either for a Black or a tihite candidate, combining votes for candidates of the same race seems the obvious thing to do and offers, in our view, tl'c best procedure for estimat'ing the magnitude of rac'ial bloc voting. However, it may be the case that the different candidates of the same race have djfferent appeal to voters of that race and/or to voters of the opposite race. A straightforward way to check for this, which, as we shall see be1ow, also provides a methodology to be used when voter registration (or population) data by race is not available, 'is to regress the vote shares for candidate j on the vote shares for candidate j, for each 'i,i pair (see below for further details). In multicand'idate races a matrix of correlation coefficjents f or each (hypothet'ical ) cand'idate pairing should be generated. in addit'ion, for each candidate we can estimate ('in a f ash'ion d'irectly analogous to that specified in Section II) the proportion of Black voters and the proportion of [.lhite voters (and for partisan elect'ions, the proportion of registered Democrats and of registered Republicans/Independents) who voted for that candidate by regressing TNV -CVS {CVSjand#withx(andw.ithPo).Suchregressionsenableus l8 enable us to "fine-tune" our analysjs to allow for variations/overlap in the support bases of different candidates of the same race. Such inter-candidate variations/overl aps may occur, for example, if candidates of the same/djfferent race are of the same/d'ifferent party. We can verify the accuracy of these regressions estjmates by comparing the mean number of ballots cast by voters'of each race (of each party) obta'ined by summing up over all candidates the voter proportions estimated as being given to each candidate from voters of a given race (or a given party) with that given by our direct estjmates of ,l^J and ng (no and nR*l). If there is racially polarized voting, then (in a single member d'istrict race) we should obta'in high negative correlat'ions between cand'idates of different races, although some candidates may be associated with more rac'ial po'larization than others. In a single-member d'istrict race with more than two candidates'is always necessary to run a regression of total vote share of White candidates versus total vote share of Black candidates. The negative correlation this g'ives us w'ill almost'invariably provide a more revealing ind'ication of probable racial polarization than will the correlations resulting from any of the two-candidate (Bl ack cand jdate vs. l^lhite candidate) regressions, since candjdates of the same race are competing *ittl each other as well as with the candidate(s) of the oppos'ite race, and candidates of the same 'ideology will be drawing some of their support from the same Hence, the magnitude of the (negative) correlations between Black and Wh'ite cand'idates'in a single member distrjct race than two cand'idates wjll understate the seeming magnitude of l9 voters .9 individual wi th more racial po1 ari zation. In multimember districts without a numbered place system, even if racial bloc voting is high, the correlation between'indjvidual pafrs of tih'ite and Black candidates may not even be negative, espec'ia11y if the candidates are of the same party, since voters possess multiple votes and it is therefore "easier" to give votes to a cand'idate or candjdates of the opposite race. 9As for candidates of the same race in an smd race with more than two candidates, we m'ight expect a positive correlation between their votes to the extent that they're drawing votes from the same types of voters; but, of course, they're also competing for voters, and this would tend to g'ive a negative corielation between the'ir vote shares across voting precincts. In general, in a multicandidate race, no clear pred'iction for the nature of the correlat'ion between the vote share of candidates of the same race can be given. ?0 V. Mod'ification to the Bas'ic Model for the S'ing1e-Member D'istrict Case for Primary rather than General Elections In a primary elect'ion (except jn the handful of states with open primaries), the only elig'ib1e voters are those who are party registrants. This means that unless this data is directly available, we must estimate party registration by race, and then'for each party's primaries substitute the (estimated) proport'ion of (Black/White) party-reg'istered votes for the proportions of registered voters in our earlier ana'lysis. Where we have data by voting precinct for both party registration and registration by race, we can estimate party reg'istration by race by running a regression of party registrat'ion by race, 'i .e., we est'imate PD, PR and Pl by using regressions based on identit'ies which must be true for the electorate as a whole. Using notation analogous to our earlier notation t.€., PD = X(P!{D) + (l - x)PgO ; PD=(fu0-Pgg)x+PBD. Hence if pD(i) = r3*1i) + b: for att i, we have P,uD=*3*b3 PBD = b3 21 In like manner vle may estimate the proportion of l.Jhite registered voters who are Republicans (i.e., PWR) and the proportion of Black reg'istered voters who are Republicans ('i.e., PBR), etc. Analogous to our earljer results PBD * Pt* 51, and P*, + Pr* 51, since some registered voters may not have a party affiliation. 0nce we have obta'ined values for PWO and PgO (PWn and PBR, PWt and Pgt) we use Bayes Theorem to specify the proportion of registered Democrats who are White, PDW, etc. as D=.DW etc. 'Ptt D-5- ,D then we use x-P*,PO-PwtPI x-P**P*-PIWP, I - LPRWPR * PIWPI * PRBPR + PIBPII I - PR - PI 'instead of x, and use 'l -x-PRgPR-PtgPl I - IPRWPR * PIWPI * PnBPR + PlgPtl- instead of I - x in the regression equat'ions (Republ ican ) primaries. If our estimates are real'istic, it must be for the Democratic the case that 22 PI.JD * Pt.lR * Pt.lI = I = PI,JD * PwlR*I1 PBD * PBR * PBI = I = PBD * Pg(R+t)' If the proportion of independent or unaffil'iated voters is low, it will be preferable to combine these voters w'ith the voters of the party which they most resemble, a'lthough 'if the percentage of independents or unaffil'iated is low it will not matter greatly which party we combine them with and so we can use PWln*t1 and PalR*t) to obtain the analogues to x and I - x for Democratic primaries and Pw(O+t; and Pg(O+t) to obtain the analogues to x and I - x for Republican primaries. In thjs case we estimate the values of, sdY, PBD, PAln+11, PWO and PWlR*11, 'in a manner simi lar to that shown above. 23 VI. Extend'ing the Basjc Model for the Single-Member District General Elect'ion Case to Al low for Different'ial Turnout and Voter Choice by Race and by Party In the previous section we showed how, if the appropriate registration data broken separately by race and by party were available' 'it was possible to calculate PWD, PBD, PWlR*t1, and Paln+t;. In the basic model'in Section II we have implicitly assumed that Black (White) turnout is (approximately) constant across voting precjncts, and so is PWW (Pgg). If these assumptions gjve rjse to regression estimates with low values of r (rZ), it may be possible to improve the reliability of our estimates of the proportion of Wh'ite/Black voters who vote for Black cand'idates by using a multivariate regression model which permits White Republicans and White Democrats (or perhaps Black Republicans and Black Democrats) to behave differently from one another. Alternatively,'if the bivariate regress'ion est'imates are good (or if we use data derived from extreme case analysis) we can use this data to obtain estimates of unknown values such as T*, and Trr. Clearly there are elections jn wh'ich we might expect that, say, tlhite Republicans and l,Jhite Democrats would behave somewhat different'ly, e.g., in an election between a Black Denpcrat and a l.lhite Republ'ican. As noted above, 'it w'ill often be the case that the number of independent voters w'il I be low and/or varying in the'ir electoral behav'ior across districts so that regression estimates for these voters as a separate category w'ill be unreliable. In that case, we can combine Independents with the party they most resemble. We present the analysis 24 for this case below. (A mult'ivariate regress'ion analysis of the case where Democrats, Republ icans and Independents are best treated separately is given in Appendix B.) (1) Tu-rnout: An equational approach. To obtain turnout by race and by party we may seek to solve the fol'low'ing set of equations 'in terms of the unknown parameters TWO, TBD, TWlR*t I and TAlR+i;: PorT*o*PDBTBD=TD P1R*t)wrw1n+t1 * t(**t)aTg(R+I) = TR*l oowT*o * o(**t)wTw(R+t) = Tt^t PoaTgo * o(**t;aTa(R+t) = TB The values of TD and TR*I, are known from regress'ing T on PR*I bY using the identitY TD(l - Pp+1) * TR*IPR+I = J The values of Ta and T',,, can also be derived either from extreme case analysis or from a regression equation (see Section II). By Bayes Theorem n*, (x) D= 'Dt.l e*r(x)-5-P,,,D(x) + PBD(l - x) D ='l -D.DB .DhI D = Pw(n*l)(') '1R+t1w - - 25 P1n*l)B=l-P1R*t1w The values of PI,lD, PWlR+I;, PBD, Pg(R*t) are estimated vja the regressions described in Section V. 0f course x and I - x are known. Wjth PD,.,, PDB, P1R+lyw, P1n+t1a and TlnI, TB, TD, and TR*I known, ,{ we can simpljfy by assuming that TBD = TBIR*I1, then we can directly solve by substitutid* Ta for TgO in the first equation on page 24 to obtai n PowTwo+PrtTt=T, Rewrjting this equation to solve for T*r, we obtain Tr^iD=# Analogouslylo r -TR*t-P(R*i)gTg 't^t1R+I) -E lOIf we attempt to solve the four equations on page 26 for TWD, etc. in terms of the known parameters we obtain PoeTao - P1R*l)wTw(n+l) = TD - Tw PowTwo * PDgTBD * P(R*l)wTw(R+t) * P1R*t)aTa(R+l) = T to*T*o - t(o*t)gTg(R+r) = TD - TB giv'ing us only three equat'ions and four unknowns since our original equation set 'is not independent (To*, * Tn = To * Tu = T). Thus we can proceed no further unless we make a''sfmplify'ing"assutllpt'ion. As above, we could reasonably simplify by letting Tp(o*r\ = Tnn. (I,Je could also assume that To/o-rr = T,.,/nrr\, but aS lOng aS"thel6 are"few CaSeS Of BlaCk RepubliElffi/inoep8rl5d*di which option we choose won't matter greatly. We can decide between them by solving under both assumpt'ions and (continued) 26 (2) Voter choice: a multivariate regression approach. For simplicity, we present our analysis with independents comb'ined with Repubf icans. We have wh'i I e P1a = [eygP1wD)14 + P1a(R+I )Pw(n*r)w] x + [PsoP(BD)1^1 + Pg(n*t)Pe(n+t)w] (l-x) ; P,,rD=P (+) Pso .I-D PwlR+r1= + -(+) Paln+r; (continued) then checking to see wh'ich set of parameters gives us a better fit.) With this first assumption, we have PogTg - t(**, )wTw1n+t; = TD - TI.J PowTwo + (PoB * P1R*I1a)Ta * P1R*I)wTw(r+t) = J PowTwo - P1n*t)BTB = To - Tg ' wh'ich can be rewritten as: (l - Pow)Ts - P1R*l)wTw1r+t1 = TD - Tht (l - tD, * I - P(R*t1w)Ta * PDwTwD * P1R*I)wTw(n+r) = J - (l - P1R*tyw)Ta = PDr^rTwD = TD - TB After some (sicl) algebraic manipulation we obtain: TI,ID = Twln+r1 These estimates will be text, and very probably not only a marginaf improvement over worth the bother to calculate. + 2(T, - TB)PDWI[arw - 2Ttrpow - 4To * 2TB * Z(T9 - Tw)p(R+t)w (R+I )l.l/.. (R+I ) t.l those i n the ?7 Hence, if we may simplify by assuming that the Black vote does not vary with party registration, i.e. t(eO)14 = PB(R+l)14 = PB14, then p, = [p, - (t-x)pup1 p(wo)w + [(l-Pe) - (l-x)Ps(R*l)] Pw(R+r)',, + Pgw(l-x) ' where P* and P1R*t) are estimated from earl'ier regressions, as'it PB,,. I,le may rewrite the above equation urll llAn ulternatjve is to use this equation to define two new variables, using Z, as an arbitrary label: ,, = r(J) - (t-x(i))pso z2 = (,-r(il)) - (r-r(i))pg(R+r), then we can specify a regress'ion equation: r,i, - psw{r-x(i), = p(wo)wZt * ptnl(n+r)wzz * b2r If the voting patterns of tlJhite Democrats/White Republicans and Independents are roughly constant across districts, then we should have bzl-o and the coefficients of the regression give us the values for P(WO)W md P11(R+I)H. In this manner, if we do w'ish to try to distinguish among Black Democrats and Black Republicans plus Independents, we can set ,(;) - pww(x(i)) = [pr-x(')rrr] p(so)w + [(l-Pr) - r(i"*,**r)] Ps(R+r),, . (continued) ?8 Pw = (l - x)[PsoP(t,,tD)hJ * Ps(R*t)Pw(R+I)tl * Pew] + Po[P(wo)w - Pw(n*i)w] JO' 'tl(R+l)W Hence, in a multivariate regression equation of PW vs I - x and PD the intercept gives us an estimate of PWln+l1W and the value of the coefficient of the PD term added to the'intercept g'ives us an estimate of P(WO)W. Similarly in a mult'ivariate regression equation of Pg vs. I - x and PD the intercept gives us an est'imate of PWln+t;A and the value of the coefficient of the PO term added to the 'intercept gives us an estimte of P(WO)g. These four values enable us to obtain the'ir primed equivalents PiwO)w, Pw(R+I),,,, etc., wh'ich are analogous to Pf^tw and Pwg. The multivariate regress'ion model given above allows us to find separate parameters for White Democrats, t,Jhite Republjcans and Blacks (or we could have used equations which, if there were sufficient numbers of Black Repubf icans and Independents to yield rel'iable est'imate, would have enab'led us to find separate parameters for Black Democrats, Black (Fontinued) However, this regression is likely to either have a low rt because of the 1ow proport'ions of Black Republicans and the low variance in this variable, or to yield_values for Pg(n+t)W and PlgO)51 which are essentially ident'ica'1. The first method given in the text, based as it'is on bas'ic rather than derived variables, appears to give more reliable parameter estimates than the method given in this footnote. However, even the first method tends to have trouble partitioning variance if the basic variables (i.e., PR+I and x) are highly correlated, and we have come to strongly prefer the substitutjon technique based on bivariate equations described in the numbered section immed'iately following th'is one as the preferred method for estimating P(91D)W, etc. 29 Republicans, Independents, and Whites). We do not have sufficient independent variables to d'istinguish by party and by race for both races sjmultaneously in a single multivariate regression equation.l2 (3) Voter choice: an equational approach. We can make use of equations most of whose parameters can be derived d'irectly or indjrectly from bivariate regressions or extreme case analysis, and then solve for unknown parameters of interest such as P(WO)W. This method seems to give considerably more reliable parameter estimates of voter choices than the multivariate techniques described above, which suffer from the problem of multicol l'inearitY. Pdvw Povg Pfn*t)vw proportion of votes cast by Democratic voters who go to the l,lhite cand'idate(s) proportion of votes cast by Democratic voters wh'ich go to the Bl ack candi date( s ) proportion of votes cast by Republjcan and Independent voters which go to the t,lhite candidate(s) proportion of votes cast by Republican and Independent voters which go to the Black cand'idate(s) P(n*l)vs l2If our bivariate regressions do not yield a good enough fit, 'it may be usefu'l to try to replace the assumption of the model in Section II that the proport'ion of Black/White voters who are registered Democrats or Repubf ican'flI@dents is constant over all voting precincts wjth a more realist'ic model which permits precinct by precinct variation in the proportions of voters of a g'iven race who are Republicans, Independents or Democrats. The multivariate model 'in numbered Section (2) of Section VI perm'its us to cons'ider precinct by prec'inct variations in the proportions of voters of a given race who are Repub'lican/Independent or Democrats, but does not permit us to look at all four possible combinations simultaneously in the same estimating equation. This is a rather technical point and we have relegated a full d'iscussion of it to Appendix B. 30 BVP = proportion of voters who are Black I,{VP = proport'ion of voters who are Wh'ite I^IDVP = proportion of voters who are registered as White Democrats WRM = proportion of voters who are registered hlhite Repubficans or Independents BDVP = proportion of voters who are registered as Black Democrats BRIVP = proportion of voters who are registered as Black Repub'licans or independents DVP = proportion of voters who are registered as Independents or Democrats RIVP = proportion of ..'oters who are registered as Republ'icans or I ndependent s t,le have Pbvw = SFPirr)r^r *HF Piao)w Pdvs = Hi Pi*olB * Hi P(so)s t^le know that wDVP=ffi BDVP=l-WDVP But WD = xP*, BD=(1-x)p* 3l while, DVP=ffi t.Je can obtain POV* and PfjVg by regressions of P!{ and PB with P1n*t) in the manner shown in Sect'ion II. If we can simplify by letting Dr = Dr - Dr '(eo)t.l - 'B(R+I)l.l - rBhJ ' which is a value known from earlier regress'ions (see Section II), then we have (DVP)Pdv!{ - (l - WDVP)Pdw P f wo)w = and Dl = I - Dl'(I.ID)B ' '(hrD)hr In like manner we can calculate the proportions of White Democrats who vote for a particular cand'idate, C, from the proportions of Democrats and Blacks who vote for that candidate. VI I. 32 Coping with the Unavailabil ity of Registration (or Population) Data by Race As noted in Sect'ion IV above, when registration (or population) data by voting precinct by race'is unavailable, it is possible to check for racial bloc voting by regressing the aggregate vote share for cand'idates of one race on the vote share of candidates of the opposit. ru...l3 l.Jh'ile a high magnitude (and negative sign) of the correlatjon coefficient between aggregate Black candidate vote share and aggregate Wh'ite candidate vote share is often taken to be sufficient evidence of racial polarization, this js jn error. For single member d'istricts, a h'igh negative correlation between Black candidate vote share and t,Jhite candidate vote share is a necessary, but not a sufficjent, condit'ion for the presence of racjal polarjzation. It is possible (although empirically unlikely) that we could obtain a high negative correlation between aggregate Black candidate vote share and aggregate t,Jhite cand'idate vote share even if (in terms of PWW and Pgg or in terms of Yule's Q or the Rice Index) only very fimited racial polarization existed. This could occur either if the Black candidate(s) and the White candidate(s) were consistently appealing to different constituencies that were differentiated along lines not (to any significant extent) related to race, or if there was a consistent pattern of Black candidates appeaf ing more strongly to Black voters and White candidates appealing more strongly to I,Jhite voters that did not involve .ery large differences I 3such a method shoul d be methods are ruled out because used, of course, only if other better of data l'imitatioffi 33 in the proportions of the votes from voters of each race that went to candidates of that same race, e.9., if hJhites consistently divided the'ir votes 5l percent - 49 percent (Llhite candidates vs. Black candidates) wh'ile Blacks in the various precincts consistently divided their votes 49 percent - 5'l percent. For l'inear relationships, the correlat'ion coefficient provides a measure of cons'istency of relationship, not magnitude of effect.l4 If we do obtain a high negative correlation between the aggregate vote shares of Black and White candidates, we would like to rule out the possibif ity that this high correlatjon could be caused by factors extraneous to race and to assure ourselves that race is indeed a factor of major importance. As suggested in Section III, we can achieve these ends by lookjng at voting precincts which are overwhelm'ingly composed of voters of one race. In such lopsided Black (White) prec'incts Black (l,lhite) candidates should be rece'iving very high (low) vote shares if indeed voting is po'larized along rac'ial l'ines. Normally, even if we do not have hard data on rac'ial proportions in each voting precinct, we st'il I wj I I have suff ic'ient "common-sense" knowledge of electoral demography to be able to isol'ate enough almost all White and almost all l4Nonetheless for single member districts if racial polarization aggregate is high, then we must obtain a high negative correlation betwebn the vote shares of ETack and White candjdates (Puf and Ps). However, for mult'imember districts without a place system the c6rrelation between Py and Pg need not even be negat'ive, even if there js consjderable rac'ial bloc voting. 0f course the correlation between Pi and Pd must be -1, since these variables are complements. 34 Black precincts to make th'is test as a double check on the reliability of a judgment of the existence of a high degree of racial bloc voting determjned on the basjs of regression(s) of candidate vote shares. 35 VIII. Modificat'ions to the Analysis for the Case of Mult'imember Districts or At-Large Elections I'lithou! a Designated Place System It is straightforward to mod'ify our analysis to deal with mmd situations where each voter may cast from 0 to k votes. Let nW = mean number of cand'idates voted for by White registered voters nB = mean number of cand'idates voted for by Black , rBgistered voters total votes castn = mean number of candidates voted for = *rffi It is apparent that i-=n*x+ng(l-x) Hence, i' is for mmds analogous to voter turnout, T, for smds, and if we regress n on. x we obtain nB=b6 n,u=16*b6 The key equations for the mmd case are ident'ities of the form Io* = n,^,(x)Pww + nr('l-x)Pr* mean # of votes x . mean # of votes (l-x) . mean # of for Hhite cast by Wh'ites for votes cast by Blacks candidates White candidates for White cand'idates. 36 Rewriti ng, we obta'in @-. ls p-:Pl,J = - n F PBwi i.e., if we regress Py on x, we obtain PB,.,= fo b7 P,,,,,= h (mr+br) 0f course, if n, = n*, then PBbl = b7 and P,,,. = *7 * b7. In like manner, by using the identity PB = n14(x)P1n1g * nB('l-x)Pgg, by regressing P3 on x t{e can 6tai n PBB= fo b8' Pr^lB= h (mr+br) Thus Dr = '** = *' * o' ' Hl'l PWbt*PWg ,g * bg + m7 + b7 and pils= ,rh =#E 37 The coeff icientr P'Wl^l and P'BB must be interpreted with great care in mmd races without a numbered place system. If, for example, there are 5 White and I Black cand'idates in a race in which voters may cast up to four votes, 'if hJhite voters were "color-blind" in the way they cast their ballots (j.e. voted w'ith equal (2/3) probability for each of the six candidates), the Black candjdates would receive exactly 1/6 of the ballots of White voters. Thus we would find a P',,,,, of .83 (5/6ths), wh'ich would on the surface appear to be evidence of highly polarized voting. For mmd races without a numbered place system, comparing the obtained PWW and Pig values with what would have been obtained had all candidates been voted for with equiprobability may help us to judge the actual degree of rac'ial polarization, but even the assumption that all cand'idates of the same race are voted for with equal probab'i'l'ity is suspect; and thus comparisons with the equiprobability model can be quite misleading. For mmd races without a place system, it'is preferable to focus on racial bloc voting as measured by the relative proportjon of l,Jhites/Blacks who vote for any given Black/White candidate.l5 For mmd elections without a place system this will prov'ide us a better *.usrre of racial bloc votjng than PWW or Pig, or the Q or R values derived from them. For mmd elections without a place system we shall develop a general technique for estjmating the proportion of White/Black voters who vote/do l5Wfrile it is possible to apply standard stat'istjcal tests to determine the'likelihood that the observed P,',,, and P:^ values could have been obtained by chance from a racially HHutrat paffern of voting, such a test will only determine the ex'istence of racial polarization and not jts magnitude. 38 not vote for any given candidate. lle can then use th'is technique to separately consider differences in the support bases of the Black and the tlhite candidate(s). In particular for the case where there 'is only a single Black candidate th'is method will yield us estimates of the proportions of t.Jhites who vote for that candidate vs. the proportion of Blacki who vote for the cand'idate, the d'ifference between whjch provides a direct measure of racial bloc voting. 39 Estimat'ing the Proportion of Whites/Blacks . |.lho Vote for a Given l'Jhite/Black Candidate 1,1e provide the analysis for the case of a Black candidate. The model i s 'identical for a Wh'ite cand'idate. As before, 1 et C. = the jth iandidate, a Black candidate J T = proportion of registered voters who turn out to vote TNV = number of registered voters who turn out to vote TB = proport'ion of Black registered voters who turn out to vote TW = proportion of l,Jh'ite registered voters who turn out to vote As noted previously, if we regress T vs x, we obta'in TB = intercept of regress'ion of T vs x Simi lar1y, Tll, = intercept of regression of T vs l-x Let BVP = proportion of voters who are Black = (1-x) IA / [xT* + (l-x) TrJ l^lVP = proportion of voters who are }lhite = *Tw / [xTw + (1-x) TgJ PilVC, = proportion of Hh'ite voters who vote for the Black candidate, Cj PfiVC, = proport'ion of Black voters who vote for the Black candidate, Cj CVS, = proport'ion of the voters who vote for the Black cand'idate, Cj 40 # of votes for the Black candidate, C, TNV For any candidate, Cj "" = ;':'; -l"..'lo':,'lJl' - 1P1lvc3-P ivc' )'uvP - Pivc' Hence, 'if we regress CVS, vs. liVP, then the PfiVCr. Sjmilarly,'if we regress CVS. vs. BVP, g i ves ut PdVC .. J Thus, to find P[ur. (PilVC.), we first regress JJ to obta'in T, 1f, ) ; then substi tute those v al ues 'i n formulae to obtain BVP (I,JVP), and use these values regress'ion of CVS, vs. BVP (CVS, vs. WVe;.16 intercept gives us then the i ntercept T vs.x (Tvs. l-x) the specjfied of BVP (h/VP ) 'i n the Estimati ng the Proporti on of tlh i telBl ack Democrats/Republ'icans who Vote for a Given l.lhite/Black Candidate in a Democratic/Republican Primary For a primary, the analyses of turnout and the racial pattern of the votes for a given cand'idate is s'imilar to the analyses for a general l6Alternatively we can define candidate j's share as a proportion of the registered voters, and then, by knowing turnout, we can specify the proportion of the reg'istered voters who didn't vote for cand'idate i. By regressing these proport'ions on x we caiTdT-cul ate PiVC. and PfiVC. from the'ir unprimed equ'ivalents, analogously to how weJcalculated Pfr* Jand Pfig from their unprimed equivalents in Section II. 4l election we have given above. 0f course, we must substitute Black/hlhjte Democrat/Republican registered voters for Black/tlhite registered voters. This requ'ires us to define registered voters in terms of only those voters eligible to vote in the given'primary (see Section V for details). 42 IX. Estimating the Proportion of Ballot Pattern of Each Possible Type Cast by Bl ack/l,lh'ite Democrat/Non Democrat Voters. The proportion of White (Black) voters who vote for no candidates of the oppos'ite race is the parameter for mmds which most closely corresponds to PWW and Pdg for smd elections. However, since there may be more than one candidate of race opposite to the voter's own contesting an election, we would also like to know to what extent voters of a given race are unwilling to vote for more than j candidates of the opposite race; since when k js large and there are several candidates of each race in the contest, "tokenism" may be present, i.e., voters may be wilfing to vote for one (or perhaps even two) candidates of the oppos'ite race but not for more. To estimate the magn'itude of racial b'loc voting in an mmd race without a numbered place system, we propose estimating the proport'ion of the t,Jh'ite (Black) electorate who vote for exactly j (0 < j S k) tJhite/Black candidates, i.e., we w'ish to ascertain what proportion of the ballots of the voters of each race include votes cast for exactly i candidates of the opposite race. However, because we don't have indiv'idual ballots, but only aggregate total s, i n an mmd race w'i thout a p1 ace system ascertai ni ng ba1 1 ot patterns is very difficult, and usually impossible. For example, 'if every voter has two votes and we observe ballot proportions for candidates one through three of (1/2,1/2,1/2), we can't readily establish the relative proportions of voters who voted for C., and Cr, C1 and Cr, C, and Cr, C., on1y, C, on1y, and C, 43 only, although we do know that, on average, voters voted for only 1'1/? cand'idates. NonetheleSS, regreSsion and simultaneous equations techniques may help us estimate Such unknown ballot proport'ions' 1^1e begin w'ith a model for reconstructing ballot patterns for exactly two of the K candidates in a given mmd race. [lle then extend th'is to reconstruct (for exactly 2 candidates) Uatlot patterns first by race and then by race and by party. Then we show how to extend the analysis to the K candidate case. The method we give can also be used to reconstruct voter ballot pattern proportions for sets of single-member-d'istrict elections taking pl ace s'imultaneously within a given jurisdiction (e.g., the votes for President, congressman' and governor within a congressional district). Let T = proportion of registered voters who vote BRT = # of registered voters who are Black lrJRT = # of registered voters who are White = I - BRT RT = # of reg'istered voters Vt = # Votes for candidate I YZ = # Votes for candidate 2 etc. WVP = proportion of voters who are Wh'ite BVP = proportion of voters who are B'lack = I - blVP Nl,lD = # of White Democrats NW(R+I ) = # of l,lhite Non-Democrats (Republ ican and Independent ) TA = proportion of Black registered voters who vote TW = proportion of t^lhite registered voters who vote 44 TNV = total number of voters .l = proportion of voters who vote for nejther candidate I or candidate 2 . rZ = proportion of voters who vote for candidate I but not candidate 2 13 = proportion of voters who vote for candidate 2 but not . cand'idate I ,4 = proportion of voters who vote for both candidate I and = candidate 2 w'ith other variables as before. Then, we have the fol low'ing two identities Vt = (13 + r+ )tt'tV YZ= (.2 *.q)Truv Moreover,'if we can assume that virtually a1l voters vote for either candidate I or candidate 2 or both, then 11 =l-T F'inal ly, 11*r2*r3+14=l V. V^ Let us denote # as ut and # as at. Specifying values for the four equations 'immediately above, and then solv'ing for the undesired unknowns we obtain 45 rl - I - T rr=T-a.' rr=T-a, 14=dl*uZ T In like manner, if we use si to represent ballot patterns of lrJh'ite voters and tj to represent ballot patterns of Black voters, we obtai n vt = (s3 + sq)wvp 'TNV + (ts + t4)(l - t,JvP) '(TNv) V2 = (s, + sO)[,lVP . TNV + (tZ + tO)(t - t^lVP) . (TNV) st - I - TW tt:l-TB tl*s2+s3+54=l tl+tZ t3+t4=l Using ,9 and b9 to represent the slope and intercept obtained by regressing Vt on WVP . TNV and ml, and btO to represent the slope and intercept obtajned by regressing UZ on t^lVP 'TNV, we obtain as a sol ut'ion ,l-l-TW yl=l-TB ,2=TW-b9-*9 2=TB-b9 *3=T1^1-btO-mlg Y3=TB-btO X4=ffig+b9 '.l0*blo*Tw J4=bg*blo-TB' We can extend this analysis to'include a breakdown of vote patterns by race and by party. Let *l = Proportion of lihite Democrats who don't vote for either candidate I or candidate 2 46 x4 = Proportion of White Democrats who vote for candidate 2 I but not candidate I etc. J1 = proport'ion of hlh ite Republ 'i cans/Unaff i I i ated who don 't vote for either Candidate I or Candidate 2 etc. If we represent ballot patterns for candidates I and 2 in vector form with a I 'indicating a vote and a 0 ind'icatjng the absence of a vote, we can represent the relevant set of regres'ion equations in matrix form as below: (oo) (ot ) (to) (il ) N[{D ^l ^Z *3 *4 Nhl(R+i) yr y? y3 y4 NBD ,) ,Z ,3 ,4 NB(R+I) qt qZ q aq # of Voters Thus, Vt = [rltlDx, + NI.l(R+i)yg * NBDz, + NB(R+I)qg * NWDxO + NI,I(R+I)yq * NBDzO + tlg(R+I)eq (*3**4)ltWO + (V3+V4) Nt^l(R+I) + (*3*24)NBD + ( o3*oa) NB(R+l ) . YZ = [rlWDx, + NW(R+I)yZ * NBDz, + NB(q+l)QZ + NWD14 + Nl,{(R+I )yq * NBDz4 + NB(R+I)qq 47 = (xZ+xiNWD + (t2*vl NI^I(R+I) + (zr+zlNBD + ( or+04) NB(R+I ) If, virtually all eligible voters who vote in the election vote for either Vt or YZ or both, then we have xl=l-TWO Y1=l-Tw(n*t) '1=l-Tgo qr =l -Ta1n*t; where TWO etc. are estimated by one of the methods described in Section III. 0f course, ,l*^Z x3+x4=l Yl *Yz* Y3+v4='l ,1*r?*zr+zo=1 Ql*Q2*q3*Q4=l Treating the first two of the above equations as regression equat'ions and the latter eight as'ident'ities, we can solve for Xi,yi,Zi, and qi ('i=l ,4) . Representing the f irst two equations as ,{ t ) = ,l') = a.,.,NWD('i) + urilw(R+I)(') + at3NBD(') + atotla(n+t)(i) ar.,ttwo(i) + arrNW(R*t)(i) *.zrNgo(i) + aroNB(n+11(i) 48 and f or notat'ional convenience, letting xl = d31r Y1 = u32, ,1 = u33, e1 = u34, we can solve for the proport'ion of Black/l,Jh'ite Democrats/ Repubficans who cast ballot patterns of each type, obtaining *l = u3l yl = u32 ,1 = u33 ql = u34 ^z = 1-al l-a31 J z = 1'a1?-a32 'z = 1-ul 3-a33 Qz = l-ul4-u34 ,3 = l-u2l-u3l y3 = l'u?Z. u3.- ,3 = l-uz3-u33 Q3 = 1-aro-aro *4 = 011+Yr.,+ar.,-l Y4 = ul ,+arr+arr-1 ,4 = u1r+arr+arr-1 94 = ul4*u24*u34-l The solut'ions specified above provide us the ballot pattern proportions we are seek'ing. If we are dealing with a primary ather than a general election we use registered Democrats/Republicans rather than registered voters. If we wish to deal with more than two candidates we simply repeat the process. For examp'le for three candidates we solve for each of the proportions Vl n V2, Vl ^ V2, Vl ^ V2, and V.t n v-r, among Black/tlhite Democrats/NonDemocrats, and then use these proportions to determine vtAV2n v3' vtn v2nv3 vtnT2nv3'vtn vz/\v3' vtn v2n v3 Tt^v2nV3 ' Vt^[2AV3' vt^v2n v3' etc. , by solving Vt n V2 = xONWD * J4N(R+I) + z4NBD + qO(R+I) V3 = .INI.ID + r2N(R+I) rrNBD + r4NB(R+i) and analogous equat'ion sets, for all the possible triples, where the values of xi,yi,Zi and a1 (i = .l,4) are known from the earlier 49 regress'ion equations.. in other words, we solve a set of equations w'ith V.1 A V2, Vt n Tr, Vt A V2, and Tt ^ [r, resPect'ive]y, substituting for Vl in our earlier equation set. It is straightforward to generalize this technique to deal w'ith a k candidate race (k > 3), or with k (k > 3) single member district races'in the same juridiction which we w'ish to simultaneously analyses. 50 proportion proportion of votes of votes to White to Black candidate(s) candidate(s) (normal i zed ) proport'i on of }lhi te regi stered voters who voted for ( a) wfri telBl ack candidate(s) ( normal i zed ) proportion of Black registered voters who voted for (a) t'lhite/Black candidate(s) votes from t'lh'ite voters total vote votes from Black voters total vote Pil Pi Tabie I Parameters of Racial Bloc Voting in a Single Member District Elect'ion Represented in a ZxZ Matrix Form Pww ,\ q-:;P--tx / Pwg ,\ 4=7rrxt ,%(r-x) ft(r-x) 5l proport j on of tJhi te voters who voted for (a) Hn'ite/Black candidate(s) proport'ion of Black voters who voted for (a) t,Jh'ite/Black candidate(s) proportion of proPortion of votes to l,lh'ite votes to Black candidate(s) candidate(s) Ptiw Pils Priw Pris Tabl e 2 Alternative Representat'ion of Parameters of Raci al Bloc Voting i n a Sing'le Member District Elect'ion in a ZxZ Matrix Form 52 Variable L'ist BD = the proport'ion of registered voters who are Black Democrats BDVP = proportion of voters who are registered as Black Democrats BOVp = proportjon of voters in a Democrat'ic primary who are BD.PDBurdC:r=p 'BP ' DB 'tlD ' Dtl BI BR = the proport'ion of registered voters who are Black Independents or Black Unaffiliated. = the proportion of reg'istered voters who are Black Republ icans = # of registered voters who are Black = proportion of Black voters who are in a Republican Primary Repubf icans or Black Independents = proportion of voters who are Black = cand i date j = proportion of the voters who vote for cand'idate, C. J = proportion of the registered voters who vote for candidate C= J = turnout of Democrats (# of Democratic voters) = proport'ion of voters who are registered as Independents or Democrats BRT BRvp BVP C. J CVP. J CVS. J DT DVP PnsTen TgRf Rg * TwR'PRt.l BRIVP = proportion of voters who are registered as Black nB 53 = mean number of candidates voted for by Black registered v oter s nD = mean number of candidates voted for by voters who are registered Democrats nR+I = mean number of cand'idates voted for by voters who are registered Republ icans or Independents n,,, = mean number of candidates voted for by Wh'ite registered voters n = mean number of cand'idates voted for = i9!9]=Y9t9t tStt regi stered voters NBD = # of Black Democrats who are registered voters NB(R+I) = # of Black Republicans plus Independents who are registered voters Nl.lD = # of White Democrat who are registered voters Nt^l(R+I ) = # of White Repubf icans p'lus Independents who are regi stered voters Pg = the proportion of total registered voters who vote for the Black candidate Pgg = the p.roportion of Black registered voters who vote for the Black candidate PgO = proportion of Black registered voters who are Democrats Pgn = proportion of Black registered voters who are Republicans Pg(R*l) = proportion of B'lack reg'istered voters who are either Republ icans or Independents PgW = the proportion of Black registered voters who vote for the t,{hite candidate 54 PD D,DB o 'Dt^l PI PR o,RB P1n+r1 P1n+r)a PRw Pw ttrt D 'I^lD P(wo)s P(wo)w PwR Pwln*t 1 proportion of proportion of proportion of Unaffiliated. proportion of = proportion of registered voters who are Democrats regi stered Democrats who registered Democrats who reg'i stered voter s wh o are Prr(l-x) PBD(l-x)+Prr(x)are Black = are tlhite = l-POg Independents or regi stered = proport'ion of reg'i stered = proport i on of reg'i stered I ndependent voters who are Republjcans Republicans who are Black = voters who are Republicans nr,(1-x) PBR(l-x)+PwR(x) or = proport'ion of registered Republicans and Independents who a re Black proportion of registered Republ icans who are !,Jhite = l-PRB. the proportion of total registered voters who vote for the l,lh'ite c and i date the proportion of White registered voters who vote for the Bl ack cand'idate proportion of h/hite registered voters who are Democrats proportion of !,lhite Democrats votes which go to Black candi dates I as a rati o of reg i stered l^lhi te Democrats] proportion of l,'lhite Democrats votes wh jch go to white candidate(s) [as a ratio of registered white Democrats] proportion of I'lhite registered voters who are Republ icans proportion of l,lh'ite registered voters who are either Repubf icans or Independents 55 Pwln*113 = proportion of white Republjcans and Independents (comb'ined) votes wh'ich go to Black candidate(s) [as a ratio of registered l,lhite Republicans and Independents] P = proportion of l,lht'ie Republ icans and Independents'hJ(R+I )51 Pr vt,vr (combined) votes whjch go to White candidate(s) [as a ratio of registered Wh'ite Republicans and Independents] PWW = the proportion of hlhite reg'istered voters who vote for the tlhite candidate Dr = O' ' B PB*PW Dr = ou, ' BB Pgw*PgB PfiOVC. = proportion of Black Democratic voters who vote for the J Black/White cand'idate, C, pl-.^ = proportion of Black Repubfican voters w'o vote for the' BRVCJ Bl ack/lJh'ite candi date, ,j pl.. = proportion of Black voters who vote for the Black/tJhjte,BVCJ canci'idate Cj D Dr = 'BW ' BtlI Pgw*PgB PliVg ' = proportion of votes cast by Democratic voters which go to the Elack candidate(s) PilVC. = proport'ion of Democratic voters who vote for the Black/ ' *h'ite candidate, cj PfjVW = proportion of votes cast by Democratic voters which go to the White candidate(s) P'tl P 'l^JB P 'tjtJ Pilovc, Pilvc, 56 Pin*l)VW = proportion of votes cast by Republican and Independent voters. wh'ich go to the Wh i te c and i date ( s ) Pin+t1Va = proportion of votes cast by Repubf ican and Independent o1 'RVCj voters which go to the Black candidate(s) = proportion of Repub'l'ican voters who vote for the Black/ Wh'ite candidate, C.l J D..l^/ = qlrB- o, hiB = -d--o- ' l.lI^J " hlB D 'l,JhJ=- Pww*Pt^t B = proport'ion of tlhite Democratic voters who vote for the Black/t',lhite candidate, C, Pfif nVC. = proportion of tJhi te Republ ican voters who vote f or the J Black/White cand'idate, rj = proport'ion of White voters who vote for the Black/White candidate, C, a R PwwPg g -PwgPgw = Rice Index of Rac'ial Polarization = PBB-PWB = D -D't.ll'/ ' Btl RDV = # of registered Democrat voters RIVP = proportion of voters who are registered as Republicans or I ndependent s = Yule's a Index of Racial Polarization = D.=:'tl!{%gffill 57 RRV = # of registered Repubf ican voters RT = total number of registered voters T = turnout as a proport'ion of registered voters TB = PBB*PB,r,'= the proportion of registered Black voters who vote TgO = proportion of Black Democrats who turn out to vote r = proport'ion of Black Republicans and Independents who turn'B(R+I ) out to vote TO = turnout proportion of registered Democrats TNV = total number of voters T0T = total number of voters TR = turnout proportion of registered Republjcans T1n*l) = turnout proportion of registered Republican and Independents combined T* = P**+P*t = the proport'ion of registered hlhite voters who vote TWO = proportion of White Democrats who turn out to vote TWR = proportion of t/hite Republicans who turn out to vote TWlR*t ) = proport'ion of [,Jhite Republ icans and Independents who turn out to vote Vj = # of votes f or cand'idate j [,lD = the proportion of registered voters who are both White and Democrats, i.e., the proport'ion of registered voters who are tJhite Democrats WDVP = proportion of voters who are registered as tJhite Democrats WOVp = proport'ion of voters in a Democratjc primary who are l,lhite = l -BDVP 58 hll = the proportion of reg'istered voters who are White Independents or !'lh'ite Unaff i I i ated l,lR = the proportion of registered voters who are White Republ icans l.lRM = the proportion of voters who are registered as White Republicans or Independents t.lRT = # of registered voters who are White WnVp = the proportion of voters in a Republican primary who are White = 1-hvp [.lVP = proportion of voters who are White x = the proportion of total reg'istration which is }Jhite l-x = the proportion of total registration which 'is Black 59 R EF EREN C ES Benson, 0. Political Science Laboratory. Columbus, 0hio: Charles, Merri11, .l969 Blacksher, James ['1. and Larry F. Menefee. "From Reynolds v. Sims to City of Mobile v. Bol1pn." Hastings Law Journal, Vo1.34, No. I (September .l982), pp. l-64. Duncan, 0. and B. Davis. "An Alternat'ive to Ecological Correlation." American Sociological Review, Vo1. l8 (.l953). Goodman, Leo A. "Ecological Regression and the Behav'ior of Ind'ividuals." American Soc'iological Review, Vol . .l8, No. 6 (December .l953), FF. 663-664. Goodman, Leo A. "Some Alternatives to Ecological Correlation." American Journal of Sociology, Vol.64, No.6 (May .l959), pp.6l0-625. Iversen, G. R. "Recovering Individual Differences in the Presence of Group and Individuaj Effects. American Journal of Sociology, Vol. 7g (1973), pp. 420-434. Jones, E. "Ecological Inference and Electoral Analysis," Journal of Interdi scipl i nary H'istory, Vol . 2 (1972) , pp . 249'269 . 60 Langbeifl, L. and A. Lichtman. Ecological Inference. Beverly Hi11s: Sage Publ icati ons, 1 978. Loewen, James. Social Science in the Courtroom. Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books,.l982. Ranney, Austin. "The Utility and Limitations of Aggregate Data in the Study of Electoral Behav'ior. " 'in A. Ranney (Ed.), Essays on the Behavior Study of Pol'itics. Urbana: Univers'ity of Illinois Press, .l962, pp. 9l-.l02. Robjnson, W.S. "Ecological Correlations and the Behavior of Ind'ividuals, " American Sociological Review, Vol. 15, No. 3 (June 1950), pF. 35.|-357. Sh'ive1y, W. P. "Ecological Inference: The Use of Aggregate Data to Study Ind'iv'iduals, " American Pol itical Science Review, Vol . 63 ( .l969), pp. I .I83-l ,l96. Shively, l,/.P. "Utilizing Exterior Evidence in Cross-Level Inference," Political Methodology, Vol. I (.l974) pp. 61-74. Stokes, D.E. "Cross-Level Inference as a Game Against Nature," In J. L. Bernd (Ed, ), Mathematical Appl'icat'ions in Po'lit jcal Science, Vol. 4 Charlottesv'ille: Univer^s'ity of V'irginia, .l969, pp. 62-83. 6l Appendix A: Other Regression Approaches It is often the case that'individuals seeking to do racial bloc voting analysis w'il1 regress Pil (i.e., the proportion of the vote wh'ich goes to the tJh'ite candi date) , on x rather than PW on x. If Pil (Pd ) is used rather than PW (Pg), great care must be taken interpreting the resulting coefficients 'lest they be wrongly understood. Indeed, unless l,lhite turnout and Bl ack turnout are 'identical (wh'ich they almost never are), it is best not to use this form of regression. If, however, it has been used, we show below how to properly interpret the result of regressi ng Pil on x. By definition Dl =.hl (Pww*Pws ) (x )Pilw * ( PBs*Psx) ( l-x) Pfl, PI^J*PB Pt^l*PB (Pww*Pws) (x)Pils * (PBs*Psp) (l-x)P[, P (P,u!{+P,,,B) (- )Tffi * (PBs*PBy) (l -x ) _ xPhtw + (l-x)PBl{ Phl * PB and 'i.e. Pd = Pgw Pgg*PBw Dl =.h, Pt,l*PB 62 But then, O+DO D. = _.!!''Blil,-.',, 'BhlPli = T; + P; txJ+ PP, ; hence Pgw = bi (Pil+PB) P,,,,,, = (mi+ui)(Pr.r*Ps) Similarly, if we regress Pil on x, we obtain Pu.B = (mi+ui )(P!J+PB) PBB = (bi )(P*+PB) To obtain P*W and P'BB, we let p,i*=#k %U.',.i,.:i)' D, = 'r, - (bl) (P!{+PB) = bliT 'BB PBg*PBW PBII,*PBB TB If l.lhite turnout and Black turnout are identical, then of course PW,.*PWB = PB*P,, and Priw =ri *bi Pris -- b'Z If, however, Black turnout is less than bJhite turnout, i.e., P,,,,,*PWB , PBB*PBl,li oS w€ might expect to be true, then 63 P',,,, * PI.,B t PB * PW , PB,. * PBB ; and, therefore, Pnr.r "i * bi Pis ,rl *bl Hence, using the coeffic'ients in the equations based on regressing Pi(PL) on x (1-x) willproducemisleadjngestimatesof Pif.r and Pilg if we fail to correct for d'ifferential turnout by race and simply take PfiW to be estimated by ni*bi and Pfig to be estimated by b). Another problem with regressing Pil(Pd) on x (l-x) is that we can often obtain slope and intercepts outside the [0,.l] range. This can readily occur if b'loc voting is high and turnout'is low. For example, 'if PBB , PW+PB, we have ni * bi. > l. 64 Append'ix B: Allow'ing for D'ifferential Voter C,hoice by Race and by Party with Republicans' Democrats, and Independents Separately Treated t.Je propose a general model of the form Pt^t = [PwoP(wo)w * PwnP(rln1xJ x * [PsoP(BD)t.t + tsnP(BR)vJ (l-x) + x(t - Pwo - PwR)P1wr)j1 * (t - x)(t - Pso - psn)P1er)w Our regressi on techni que f or est'imati ng P,,D, P,.,R, PBD, etc. gi ven 'in the text above yields P. o = D - l-x p 't.lD x x BD o D ='R _ l-x p'l.JR x x 'BR D='l-D-P. t.ll ' l^lD 'I.JR PBI=l-PgO-Ogn Al so Pr.rr = I + + Psn -3. + rr, -P Hence, we may rewrite our equation for PW in terms of only five parameters, PBD, PBR, PD, PR and x: 65 Pw = [e, - (l-x) PBD] P(1n1D)r,J * [PR - (l-x) Psn] P(wn)ur + (1-x) [PgoP(BD)r^t * PBRP(a*)*] + [x - Po * (l-x) PBD - PR * (l-x) PBR] P(1ar)1nt + (l-x)(l - Pso - PsR) Plar)w trr(') ano tr*(') u.. assumed to be approximately constant for all i. If we assume each is known from a regression run of Black registrat'ion by Democratic registration, we may rewrite our equations above in terms of four variables--each of which in turn is a function of the three bas'ic variables x, PD, and PR. er(i) - t-x('i) pso p(wo)w * p*(i) - t-x(j) PsR P(wn)w + x(i)-er(i)+ r-*(i, rr,-e*(i)+ r-*(i, rr* p(wr)r * 1t-r(i), [(t-pso - paR) t(rr)1n1 *'psop(BD)1^1 + psnp(an1wJ Unfortunately, we have four subsidiary variables but only three 'independent variables x, PD, and P* and thuS our est'imates of the parameters of our regress'ion must be unreliable. To cope with this, we may simpt'ify by letting t(rr)* = P(aR;w = Pow. Then the last term of the equation above simplifies to {r-x(i), Paw 66 Transferring the last term to the left-hand side, we obtain an equation with only three independent varjables on the right-hand sjde. t(fr) - (t-*(i ))psw = r,yr * ^1ztz * *r3y3 * b, , where the yi corresponds to the variables specified in the equation direcly above, i.e., pD(i) - (t-x(i))pgo , pR(i) - (t-x(i))pgn , x('i) - er(i) + (r-x(i))peo - e*(i) + 1r-x(i))pgn . Then we have t(*r)h/ = mt j o(**)t^t = mt2 P(*r)r.,t = mr3 If the assumpt'ions used to generate these relat'ionships are reasonable, then we should also obta'in btt - o ' In ljke manner, we may readily establish equivalent equations for PB. Hence, i t 'is stra'ightf orward to calcul ate the proport'ions of White/Black Republ jcans/Democrats/lndependents who vote for a candidate of their own race. By substituting P(wo)w and t(uo)g (or P(wl )w and t(gr)gr or^ P(Wn)W and t(t*)r) for PWW and PgA in the formulae given in Section IiI of this paper (see Tables I and 2), we may calculate racial polarizat'ion separately for Democratic, Republican, and Independent voters. Alternat'ive1y, we may calculate, as before' an overall value of P WW (Pge, etc. ) by solving 67 Pwt,t = P(wo)wPt^tp * P(*R)wPwo * P(rt )wPttt PBB = P(eo)BPBD * t(t*)BPBR * P(gt)sPst etc. Remember, however, that Pl^lH * Pl,tB 5 l, PBB * PBt{ . l, and e* + e, : 1 as previously, since some registered voters may not vote. Thus, we would normally w'ish to look at the normalized values PilW, P{t, etc. The model given above allows precinct by precinct variation for voters of one race, but not for voters of both races. We could al1ow for precinct by precinct variat'ions in party membership proportions in the model offered above for Black voters'instead of for tlh'ite voters, but we do not have sufficient independent information to do so for both l'lhites and Blacks simultaneously. in effect, as we show below, we have three equations in six urknowns. Three of these unknowns can be estjmated at the aggregate level and assumed to be constant in all voting prec'incts. Let |.JD = the proport'ion of reg'istered voters who are both White and Democrats, i.e., the proportion of registered voters who are White Democrats l.JR = the proport'ion of reg'istered voters who are l'lhite Republ jcans t,JI = the proportion of registered voters who are tJhite Independents or tihi te Unaff i l i ated 68 BD = the proport'ion of registered voters who are Black Democrats BR = the proportion of registered voters who are Black Republ icans BI = the proportion of registered voters who are Black Independents or Black Unaffjliated And as before, 'let x = the proportion of registered voters who are l.Jh'ite l-x = the proportion of registered voters who are Black PO = the proportion of reg'istered voters who are regi stered Democrats PR = the proportion of registered voters who are regi stered Republ icans PI = the proportion of registered voters who are regi stered as Independents or Unaff i l i ated Cl ear 1y WD=xP*, WR=xP** lrll=xP*r=x(1 -PWO-PWn) 39 = (1-x) PgO 3P = (1-x) PgR BI = (1-x) Pr, = (1-x) (l - PgO - Pgn). 69 Since the party reg'istration of minority voters will generally be lopsidedly Democratic in all vot'ing precincts in which minority voters may be found, the party registrat'ion of m'inority voters wil I be relat'ive1y insensitive to precinct by prec'inct variations. Let us estimate PgO and Pgp from the regression technique outlined in Sect'ion V. 0nce we obtain PBD and Pgq, we may obta'in BD (and BR) by mult'ip1y'ing PgO (Pan) by l-x. We may then determine BI e'ither via the same technique or by mak'ing use of the identity BD + BR + BI = l-x. Five other i dent'ities are usef ul : l,lD+t.JR+[.lI=x tlD+BD =PD tlR+BR =PR WI + BI = PI PD*PR+PI=l For each voting precinct, i, we may set up a system of three equat'ions in three unknowns by using the first three of these last five equations, treat'ing PgO and PgR (and Pgl) as known from regression analyses and assumed to be constant across a'l 1 voting prec i ncts : 70 t*r(') *(i) * tr*(i) x(i) * p,,,r('i) x(i) = r(i) ,*r(') *{i) * pso(t-*(i); = pr(i) . r**(') x(i) * pBR(t-x(t)) = e*(i). Solving this equation set we obtain t*Jt) = l,le may now set x(i)- e*(i)- tr(i)+ (PBR+ PBD)1r-*,(i)) e*(i) = *(i) ,ro(i) e1yo1w * ,.( j ) p11R(i ) p(wr )w * *(i)ptlr(j) P(wr)w + 1't-x(i))(psoP(so)w * PgnP(sR)w * PsrP(ar1y) Substituting in the equation set above the values previously obtained for ,*r(' ), ,**(') und ,*, ( t ), we have the same result obtai ned earlier, to wit: x(i) 71 p,^,(i ) = [pD(t,- rr*(r-*(')] r(hrD)h.t + [pR(, )- rr*(r-*(1))] p(wn)w *;*(i,- t*,',- to,i)* (t-r(i))(psn* eur)1 + (t-x( i ))tpsoP(ao1w* PsRPsR(w)* PgrPlai;w1 And, as before, we set t(rr)1n1 = P(BR)1J = P(BI)14 = PBtt and move the last term over to the left-hand side to obtain three independent variables on the right-hand side. As can be seen from the analysis above, the model given above does permit the proport'ion of White voters who are Repub'l'icans/Democrats/Independents to /ary across voting precjncts. In each precinct the three proportions ,*r('), t**(') und t*r(t) u.. obtained via the solut'ion to a set of simultaneous equations. The values so obtained are then entered into the regression equation used to estjmate P(wo)w, P(wR)w' and P(wt)w' The regression equation with e*(l) - (l-x)(i) PgW as the dependent variable does not, however, provide us with sufficient informat'ion to disaggregate the parametert P(BD)1.,, P(gR)W, and O(tt)*t and so we may e'ither as before, make the strongly simpf ifying assumption that o -o - D -p'(BD) (BR)t^l - '(Br)t,l - 'BhJ' or determine those three parameters by running the appropriate regression on e*(i)- ,(')tr* rather than on Pw - (t-*(i ))or*, o. (for simplic'ity) we may estimate these parameters from jnformation derjved from voting patterns in districts which are overwhelmingly minority in population.