Effects of Multimember State House and State Senate Districts in Eight North Carolina Countries, 1978-1982 Draft Paper
Working File
May 20, 1983

Cite this item
-
Case Files, Thornburg v. Gingles Working Files - Guinier. Effects of Multimember State House and State Senate Districts in Eight North Carolina Countries, 1978-1982 Draft Paper, 1983. d38c230a-dd92-ee11-be37-6045bdeb8873. LDF Archives, Thurgood Marshall Institute. https://ldfrecollection.org/archives/archives-search/archives-item/4d371cd2-ced0-494e-b227-22e24c37b379/effects-of-multimember-state-house-and-state-senate-districts-in-eight-north-carolina-countries-1978-1982-draft-paper. Accessed April 06, 2025.
Copied!
EFFECTS OF I{ULTII{E1.IBER STATE HOUSE AND STATE SENATE DISTRICTS IN EIGHT NORTH CAROLINA COUNTIES, I978-I982 Bernard Grofman Prof essor of Pol'lt'lcal Sc'lence School of Soclal Sclences Unlverstty of Callfornla, Irvlne Irvlne, Callfornla 92717 Draft (Appendtces Incomplete) l{ay 20, 1983 I. Ef f ects of [,lul tlmember Dl str lcts: A Theoretlcal Overvlew Apportlonment schemes at the state and local level often make use of multlmember dlstrlcts (rmnds), the polar type of whlch ls, of course, the at-large electlon. Such plans typ'lca11y a'llocate the number of representatlves to a dlstrlct 1n dlrect proportlon to that dlstrlct's popttlatlon, wlth each voter ellglble to cast as many votes as there are seats to be f'llled, and candldates elected on the basls of elther slmp'le p1ura11ty or maJorlty runoff provlslons. In the aftermath of the Supreme Court's entrance lnto the "po11t1ca1 tlcket" of reapportlonment, the constltutlonallty of multlmember dlstrlcts has been challenged and partlcular rmd plans struck down. In areas wlth substantlal mlnor'lty populatlon and patterns of polarlzed votlng, mmd often have invldlous effects on mlnorlty representatlon. F1rst, and most lmportantly, multlmember dlstrlcts often act so as to submerge raclal or 11ngu1st1c (or po11t1cal) m1nor1t1es. For mmds, the "wlnner-take-all" character of p1ura1lty (or maJorlty run-off) electlons creates the strong poss1b111ty that a speclflc maJorlty w1'11 elect ali the representatlves from the dlstrlct, especlally'lf votlng 1s po'larlzed; whereas the outvoted mlnorlty.m'lght have been able to elect some representatlves 1f the multlmember dlstrlct had been broken up lnto several slng1e-member dlstr'lcts, especlaly 1f mlnorlty strength 1s geographlcally concentrated. Thls mlnorlty submergence can operate 1n both prlmarles and general electlons. Especlally when mlnorlty candldates are so unllkely of success that there are few 1f any mlnorlty candldates 1n any glven context, add'ltlonal probable consequences of m'lnorlty submergence are reduced turnout and reduced lnterest 1n po11t1cs among voters 1n the mlnortty.l A second (and closely related) problem of multlmember dlstrlcts arlses from the propenslty of representatlves from such dlstrlcts to act as a bloc. 0ften chosen large'ly by the same subset of voters, predomlnantly or excluslvely of the same party, the ldentlty of lnterests among the group of representatlves elected from a mrnd can be expected to be greater than that whlch would have arlsen had representatlves been chosen from dlstlnct dlstrlcts. Thus the set of representatlves elected from a glven mmd mlght not fu1'ly mlrror the vlews of all the cltlzens 1n the dlstrlct. In partlcular, representatlves elected from mmds may be unresponslve to the mlnorlty groups 1n the dlstrlct whose candldate(s) they have defeated. A thlrd (and related) prob'lem wlth mu'lt'lmember dlstrlcts 1s that they often lead to the electlon of representatlves who are not broadly geographlcally representatlve of the area whlch they are supposed to represent. Frequent'ly 1n multlmember dlstrlcts many or all of the representatlves wlll reslde w1th1n a llmlted geographlc area,2 unless there 1s a rule requlrlng representatives to reslde 1n geographlcally deslgnated dl str'lcts.3 A fourth problem of multlmember dlstrlcts 1s that they s1gnlf1cant1y lncrease the cost of campalgnlng by requ'lrlng campalgn'lng among a much larger electorate. Thls wlll often work to.dlscourage candldates from raclal or 11ngu'lst1c mlnorltles who are less able to afford the cost of a large-sca1e campalgn. (See Jewell, .l982, for data from a number of states bearlng on thls po1nt. )4 Dut. from the Charlotte Clty Councll and Ralelgh Clty Councll electlons of .l979 and .l98.l, electlons whlch had both a dlstrlct and at-1arge (multlmember) component, shows clearly that successful multlmember campalgns are more costly than successful s1ng1e member dlstrlct campalgns for both lncumbent and non-lncumbent candldates ( see Appended Report. ) A flfth argument agalnst multlmember dlstrlcts, only lndlrectly related to the lssue of mlnorlty submergence, ls that the tle between a representatlve and h1s/her constltuency'ls weakened when a voter does not have a s1ng1e representatlve to regard as,rh'ls own." (See Jewel'1, .l982, for support of thls argument based on surveys of state leglslators. ) In state leglslatures, multlmember dlstr'lcts are becom'lng iess common Slne the early .l970's the Justlce Oepartment has dlscouraged the use of multlmember dlstrlcts 1n states wlth slgnlflcant raclal or'llngulstlc mlnorlty populatlons 1n Jurlsdlctlons covered by Sectlon 5 of the Votlng Rlghts Act. As a result, a number of Southern states have ceased or nearly ceased leglslatlve use of mmds 1n countles subJect to Justlce preclearance. In state lower (upper) houses 1n .l968,66% 146%l used some mu1tlmember dlstrlcts, but by .l978, only 40% (26%l d1d so. (Berry and Dye,.I979:86-87.) By .l980, the percentages hrere further reduced to 38% for state louer houses and 22% for state upper houses. In .l98.l, the Amerlcan Bar Assoclatlon adopted a resolution urglng that pure s1ngle-member dlstrlctlng be adopted 1n both houses of all state 'leglslatlves. Footnotes lFor demonstratlon of how raclal bloc votlng and mlnorlty submergence operates 1n North Carollna mmds see appended summary tab'les on North Carollna House and Senate prlmary and general electlons 1n elght Nor th Carol I na count 1 es , I 978-82. 2Euld.n.. whlch bears on thls argument as 1t applles to North Carol I na 1 s g1 ven 1 n an appended repor t. 30f .orrr., use of deslgnated representailves provldes no cure for the baslc problem of mlnorlty submergences 1n mmd electlons, and may even make 'lt worse by creat'lng dlrect head-on-head Black vs. l.Jhlte conte;t. 40.t. on campalgn costs 1n Hawallan slng'le and multlmember leglslatlve electlons'ls found'ln the transcrlpts of testlmony taken 1n by 1982 the Hawa11 Reapportlonment commlsslon (see e.g., remarks by Representat'lve Toguch'l ); and a complete body of evldence f or Hawa11 leglslatlve electlon drawn from actual campalgn expendlture records, ls found 1n Exhlblt #27 of Travls v. Klnq (U.S.D1str1ct Court for the State of Hawail, Harch .l982), the l{arch .l5,.l982, deposltlon of James Ha11, a Reapportlonment Commlsslon member. Thls data fu11y substantlates the vlew that multlmember dlstrlct campalgns are more expenslve than s 1ng1e-member d'ls tr 1c t campal gns . Refer enc es Berry, Barbara L. and Thomas R. Dye. "The Dlscrlmlnatory Effects of At-Large Electlons,'r Florlda State Unlversl ty Law Revlew, Vol . 7 (1979), 85-122. Grofman, Bernard N. Resport on the constltutlonallty of the Hawa11 Reapportlonment Corrnlsslon' s proposed state 1eg'lslatlve redlstrlctlng. Prepared test'lmony 1n Travls et al. v. K1ng, U.S. Dlstrlct Court for the State of Hawail, Harch 23-24, .l982, photo-offset. Jewel I , l{alcolm E. "The Consequences of Slng'le- and l{ul t1-l{ember Dlstr1ct1ng. " In B. Grofman, A. LlJphart, R. HcKay and H. Scarrour (Eds. ), Representatlon and Redlstr'lctlnq Issues. Lexlngton, FlA: Lex'lngton Books , I982, .I29-.l35 .